Ashamed to be Selfish

We study a two-stage choice problem, where alternatives are allocations between the decision maker (DM) and a passive recipient. The recipient observes choice behavior in stage two, while stage one choice is unobserved. Choosing selfishly in stage two, in the face of a fairer available alternative, may inflict shame on DM. DM has preferences over sets of alternatives that represent period two choices. We axiomatize a representation that identifies DM's selfish ranking, her norm of fairness and shame. Altruism is the most prominent motive that can explain non-selfish choice. We identify a condition under which shame to be selfish can mimic altruism, when only stage-two choice is observed by the experimenter. An additional condition implies that the norm of fairness can be characterized as the Nash solution of a bargaining game induced by the second-stage choice problem. The representation is generalized to allow for finitely many recipients and applied to explain a social decision maker's incentive for obfuscation.

[1]  Daniel Friedman,et al.  Revealed Altruism , 2005 .

[2]  John H. Miller,et al.  NOTES AND COMMENTS GIVING ACCORDING TO GARP: AN EXPERIMENTAL TEST OF THE CONSISTENCY OF PREFERENCES FOR ALTRUISM , 2002 .

[3]  E. Fehr A Theory of Fairness, Competition and Cooperation , 1998 .

[4]  Marco Mariotti,et al.  Fair Bargains: Distributive Justice and Nash Bargaining Theory , 1999 .

[5]  Ariel Rubinstein,et al.  A Course in Game Theory , 1995 .

[6]  F. B. Vernadat,et al.  Decisions with Multiple Objectives: Preferences and Value Tradeoffs , 1994 .

[7]  Jawwad Noor Menu-Dependent Self-Control , 2015 .

[8]  Robyn M. Dawes,et al.  What you don't know won't hurt me: Costly (but quiet) exit in dictator games , 2006 .

[9]  Magnus Johannesson,et al.  Non-reciprocal altruism in dictator games , 2000 .

[10]  A. Buss Self-consciousness and social anxiety , 1980 .

[11]  Larry G. Epstein,et al.  Cold Feet , 1887, The Hospital.

[12]  Jonathan Barzilai,et al.  On the foundations of measurement , 2001, 2001 IEEE International Conference on Systems, Man and Cybernetics. e-Systems and e-Man for Cybernetics in Cyberspace (Cat.No.01CH37236).

[13]  Madan M. Pillutla,et al.  BEING FAIR OR APPEARING FAIR: STRATEGIC BEHAVIOR IN ULTIMATUM BARGAINING , 1995 .

[14]  William S. Neilson Axiomatic reference-dependence in behavior toward others and toward risk , 2006 .

[15]  R. L. Keeney,et al.  Decisions with Multiple Objectives: Preferences and Value Trade-Offs , 1977, IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics.

[16]  J. Nash THE BARGAINING PROBLEM , 1950, Classics in Game Theory.

[17]  H. Lewis Shame and guilt in neurosis. , 1971, Psychoanalytic review.

[18]  张谷 实验经济学(Experimental Economics)研究思路及成果应用简述 , 1994 .

[19]  R. Luce,et al.  Simultaneous conjoint measurement: A new type of fundamental measurement , 1964 .

[20]  Karni,et al.  The Hexagon Condition and Additive Representation for Two Dimensions: An Algebraic Approach. , 1998, Journal of mathematical psychology.

[21]  John E. Roemer,et al.  Interpersonal Comparisons of Well-Being , 1991 .

[22]  D. Fessler,et al.  Nobody's watching? Subtle cues affect generosity in an anonymous economic game. , 2005 .

[23]  Larry G. Epstein,et al.  An axiomatic model of 'cold feet' , 2007 .

[24]  William S. Neilson A theory of kindness, reluctance, and shame for social preferences , 2009, Games Econ. Behav..

[25]  Faruk Gul,et al.  A Simple Theory of Temptation and Self-Control , 2005 .

[26]  M. Rabin,et al.  UNDERSTANDING SOCIAL PREFERENCES WITH SIMPLE TESTS , 2001 .

[27]  Peter J. Hammond,et al.  Interpersonal Comparisons of Well-being: Interpersonal comparisons of utility: Why and how they are and should be made , 1990 .

[28]  Colin Camerer Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction , 2003 .

[29]  Felix Oberholzer-Gee,et al.  Fairness in Extended Dictator Game Experiments , 2008 .

[30]  Jaap Van Brakel,et al.  Foundations of measurement , 1983 .

[31]  Norman Frohlich,et al.  Some doubts about measuring self-interest using dictator experiments: the costs of anonymity , 2001 .

[32]  K. Scherer,et al.  Relating situation evaluation to emotion differentiation: Nonmetric analysis of cross-cultural questionnaire data. , 1988 .

[33]  M. Carroll The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press , 1970 .

[34]  Gary E. Bolton,et al.  Dictator game giving: Rules of fairness versus acts of kindness , 1998, Int. J. Game Theory.

[35]  G. Tullock Economics of income redistribution , 1982 .

[36]  Aldo Rustichini,et al.  Temptation-Driven Preferences , 2009 .

[37]  R. Grigg Shame and Guilt , 2005 .

[38]  M. Rabin,et al.  Understanding Social Preference with Simple Tests , 2001 .

[39]  Donald Wittman,et al.  Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results , 1989, Journal of Political Economy.

[40]  Steven D. Levitt,et al.  What Do Laboratory Experiments Measuring Social Preferences Reveal About the Real World , 2007 .

[41]  Stephen Morris,et al.  On the Form of Transfers to Special Interests , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.

[42]  J. Tirole,et al.  Incentives and Prosocial Behavior , 2005 .

[43]  Roberto A. Weber,et al.  Exploiting Moral Wriggle Room: Behavior Inconsistent with a Preference for Fair Outcomes , 2004 .

[44]  Steven Tadelis,et al.  The Power of Shame and the Rationality of Trust , 2007 .

[45]  Tore Ellingsen,et al.  Is generosity involuntary , 2007 .

[46]  Alexander K. Koch,et al.  Giving in Dictator Games: Regard for Others or Regard by Others? , 2005, Southern Economic Journal.

[47]  Faruk Gul,et al.  Temptation and Self‐Control , 1999 .

[48]  Terence C. Burnham,et al.  Engineering altruism: a theoretical and experimental investigation of anonymity and gift giving , 2003 .

[49]  Dale T. Miller,et al.  The norm of self-interest. , 1999, The American psychologist.

[50]  M. Bacharach Two-person Cooperative Games , 1976 .

[51]  R. Sugden,et al.  Rationality, Justice and the Social Contract Themes From Morals by Agreement , 1993 .