A Mixed Relationship: Bureaucracy and School Performance

We argue the negative relationship between school bureaucracy and school performance that is commonly reported in the bureaucracy and educational policy literature is theoretically and empirically incomplete. Like most public agencies operating in complex task environments, we suggest that schools have to make trade-offs between the multiple outputs they are expected to produce. Bureaucracy plays an important role in determining the nature of these trade-offs: one that is more multidimensional than it is portrayed in the existing literature. We find bureaucracy's relationship with school performance depends on how performance is measured. It is negatively associated with test scores but positively associated with other performance measures such as attendance and dropout rates. This is consistent with an economies-of-scope perspective of bureaucracy, which emphasizes bureaucracy's role in managing the trade-offs inherent in pursuing multiple goals.

[1]  Patrick J. Wolf,et al.  Representative Bureaucracy and Harder Questions: A Response to Meier, Wrinkle, and Polinard , 2001, The Journal of Politics.

[2]  J. Bohte,et al.  School Bureaucracy and Student Performance at the Local Level , 2001 .

[3]  L. Hoffman,et al.  A Recommended Approach to Providing High School Dropout and Completion Rates at the State Level. Technical Report. , 2000 .

[4]  Limits of the market metaphor , 1982 .

[5]  R. King,et al.  The Relationship Between School Spending and Student Achievement: A Review and Analysis of 35 Years of Production Function Research. , 1998 .

[6]  Janet C. Vinzant,et al.  Governance Lessons , 1999 .

[7]  Politics, Bureaucrats, and Schools. , 1994 .

[8]  Gene V. Glass,et al.  Politics, Markets, and America's Schools , 1990 .

[9]  Terry M. Moe,et al.  Politics, Markets, and the Organization of Schools , 1988, American Political Science Review.

[10]  B. Baltagi,et al.  Econometric Analysis of Panel Data , 2020, Springer Texts in Business and Economics.

[11]  What Do Schools Produce? Implications of Multiple Outputs in Education , 2000 .

[12]  E. Callan Creating Citizens: Political Education and Liberal Democracy , 1997 .

[13]  C. Goodsell The Case For Bureaucracy , 1983 .

[14]  Gordon Tullock,et al.  The Politics of Bureaucracy. , 1966 .

[15]  Edgar K. Browning,et al.  Microeconomic Theory and Applications , 1986 .

[16]  C. Belfield The Effects of Competition on Educational Outcomes , 2003 .

[17]  K. Meier,et al.  Representative Bureaucracy and Distributional Equity: Addressing the Hard Question , 1999, The Journal of Politics.

[18]  Lois W. Sayrs Pooled Time Series Analysis , 1990 .

[19]  J. Henig Rethinking School Choice: Limits of the Market Metaphor , 1995 .

[20]  Eric A. Hanushek,et al.  Throwing money at schools , 1981 .

[21]  Eric A. Hanushek,et al.  Assessing the Effects of School Resources on Student Performance: An Update , 1997 .

[22]  Kevin B. Smith,et al.  Money Only Matters if You Want It To? Exposing the Normative Implications of Empirical Research , 2003 .

[23]  J. Wyckoff,et al.  Primary and secondary school choice among public and religious alternatives , 1992 .

[24]  D. Rubinfeld,et al.  Econometric models and economic forecasts , 2002 .

[25]  A. Zellner An Efficient Method of Estimating Seemingly Unrelated Regressions and Tests for Aggregation Bias , 1962 .

[26]  Kenneth J. Meier,et al.  BUREAUCRACY AND ORGANIZATIONAL PERFORMANCE: CAUSALITY ARGUMENTS ABOUT PUBLIC SCHOOLS , 2000 .

[27]  Warren S. Eller,et al.  Zen and the Art of Policy Analysis: A Response to Nielsen and Wolf , 2001, The Journal of Politics.

[28]  B. J. Reed,et al.  New Public Management and Substantive Democracy , 2001 .

[29]  W. Niskanen Bureaucracy and representative government , 1971 .

[30]  Frederick M. Hess Spinning Wheels: The Politics of Urban School Reform , 1998 .