Aggregation (in-)variance of shared responsibility: A case study of Australia

Abstract This article deals with shared producer and consumer responsibility, a concept aimed at overcoming the non-additivity, or double-counting problem in corporate and national sustainability reporting. It reports on the potentially distorting effects that varying sector and business classifications could have on the apportioning of emissions (or other sustainability measures) amongst producers and consumers in an economy. A quantitative (in-)variance analysis is provided which shows that shared-responsibility formulations are remarkably stable under extreme aggregation of the underlying input–output data. Value-added pegging of the sharing parameters generally reduces variance in comparison to constant sharing parameters. These results help in substantiating the robustness of the shared-responsibility concept, a feature which is critically important if shared responsibility were to become corporate and national reporting practice.

[1]  M. Lenzen,et al.  Shared producer and consumer responsibility — Theory and practice , 2007 .

[2]  Roger L. Burford,et al.  The effect of aggregation on the output multipliers in input-output models , 1981 .

[3]  Lennart Karlson,et al.  Business incentives for sustainability: a property rights approach , 2002 .

[4]  Gerhard Wagenhals,et al.  Reducing CO2 Emissions , 1993 .

[5]  A. Steenge Input–output theory and institutional aspects of environmental policy , 1999 .

[6]  Manfred Lenzen,et al.  Endogenising capital: a comparison of two methods , 2004 .

[7]  J. Szyrmer,et al.  Input—Output Coefficients and Multipliers from a Total-Flow Perspective , 1992 .

[8]  A. Steenge On Background Principles for environmental Policy: "Polluter pays", "User pays" or "Victim pays"? , 1997 .

[9]  Jesper Munksgaard,et al.  CO2 accounts for open economies: producer or consumer responsibility? , 2001 .

[10]  Manfred Lenzen,et al.  Integrating sustainable chain management with triple bottom line accounting , 2005 .

[11]  The Coase Theorem, Economic Lineage and the Small Numbers Problem , 2004 .

[12]  Walter D. Fisher Criteria for Aggregation in Input-Output Analysis , 1958 .

[13]  G. J. Karaska,et al.  VARIATION OF INPUT‐OUTPUT COEFFICIENTS FOR DIFFERENT LEVELS OF AGGREGATION† , 1968 .

[14]  Geoffrey J. D. Hewings,et al.  The Effect of Aggregation on the Empirical Identification of Key Sectors in a Regional Economy: A Partial Evaluation of Alternative Techniques , 1974 .

[15]  Robert E. Ulanowicz,et al.  The effects of taxonomic aggregation on network analysis , 2002 .

[16]  Wassily Leontief,et al.  An Alternative to Aggregation in Input-Output Analysis and National Accounts , 1967 .

[17]  P. Cerin Introducing Value Chain Stewardship (VCS) , 2006 .

[18]  Stephen D. Casler Correcting input-output coefficients for capital depreciation , 1983 .

[19]  Malcolm James Beynon,et al.  Considering the effects of imprecision and uncertainty in ecological footprint estimation: An approach in a fuzzy environment , 2008 .

[20]  A. M. Wolsky,et al.  Approximate aggregation and error in input-output models , 1982 .

[21]  C. Milana,et al.  DIRECT AND INDIRECT REQUIREMENTS FOR GROSS OUTPUT IN INPUT–OUTPUT ANALYSIS(*) , 2006 .

[22]  Wassily Leontief Input-Output Economics , 1966 .

[23]  M. Lenzen,et al.  A consistent input–output formulation of shared producer and consumer responsibility , 2005 .

[24]  Alberto Heimler,et al.  Linkages and Vertical Integration in the Chinese Economy , 1991 .

[25]  Pontus Cerin,et al.  Bringing economic opportunity into line with environmental influence: A discussion on the Coase theorem and the Porter and van der Linde hypothesis , 2006 .

[26]  Kenjiro Ara,et al.  THE AGGREGATION PROBLEM IN INPUT-OUTPUT ANALYSIS , 1959 .