BUREAUCRACY AND ORGANIZATIONAL PERFORMANCE: CAUSALITY ARGUMENTS ABOUT PUBLIC SCHOOLS

as schools take actions that are linked to improved performance. ew contemporary public policies are as controversial as school choice. School privatization advocates argue that market-based school systems can educate students better than public schools. Chubb and Moe (1988, 1990), for example, contend that the institutional features of the public school system-particularly its bureaucratic structure and democratic governance-make it an ineffective organization that depresses student performance. Their remedy is to convert schools into more market-based institutions with less bureaucracy and less democratic control (Chubb and Moe 1988, 1990). Opponents of school choice contend the proponents' arguments lack empirical support, fail to consider the multiple goals of public education, and support policies that generate more costs than benefits (Henig 1994; Paris 1995; Witte 1992; Smith and Meier 1995). Lost in the public debate is the realization that some points of dispute are important theoretical questions in their own right. Both Chubb and Moe (1990) and their harshest and somewhat intemperate critics (Smith and Meier 1994) use neo-institutional arguments derived from organization theory. Some issues at dispute, as a result, are relevant not only to public policy debates but are also testable propositions that promise theoretical insight into how institutions respond to and influence their environments (Thompson 1967; March and Olsen 1989). This research examines one small, but crucial, empirical question in the school choice debate-what is the relationship between levels of bureaucracy and organizational performance? Chubb and Moe (1990) contend that bureaucracy leads to poor performance on the part of public schools. Smith and Meier (1994), in contrast, argue that bureaucracy is an adaptation to poor performance, that when organizations recognize their

[1]  Samuel J. Best,et al.  Establishing The Micro Foundations of a Macro Theory: Information, Movers, and the Competitive Local Market for Public Goods , 1993, American Political Science Review.

[2]  T. Moe,et al.  Presidents and the Politics of Structure , 1994 .

[3]  G. Burtless,et al.  Does money matter? : the effect of school resources on student achievement and adult success , 1997 .

[4]  A. F. Darrat,et al.  HAVE LARGE BUDGET DEFICITS CAUSED RISING TRADE DEFICITS , 1988 .

[5]  E. Hanushek,et al.  Who chooses to teach (and why) , 1995 .

[6]  J. Oakes,et al.  Keeping Track: How Schools Structure Inequality. , 1986 .

[7]  Kenneth J. Meier,et al.  Representative democracy and representative bureaucracy: examining the top-down and bottom-up linkages , 1994 .

[8]  Nathaniel Beck,et al.  Nuisance vs. Substance: Specifying and Estimating Time-Series-Cross-Section Models , 1996, Political Analysis.

[9]  B. Nye Smaller Classes Really Are Better. , 1992 .

[10]  Paula D. McClain,et al.  Black and Hispanic Socioeconomic and Political Competition , 1990, American Political Science Review.

[11]  G. Weiher WHY REDISTRIBUTION DOESN'T WORK , 1988 .

[12]  B. W. Brown Why governments run schools , 1992 .

[13]  James A. Stimson Regression in Space and Time: A Statistical Essay , 1985 .

[14]  Zulmara Cline,et al.  A Case Study Analysis of within District School Funding Inequities. , 1996 .

[15]  J. Witte Private school versus public school achievement: Are there findings that should affect the educational choice debate? , 1992 .

[16]  Kenneth J. Meier,et al.  The Case Against School Choice: Politics, Markets and Fools , 2016 .

[17]  Kevin B Smith,et al.  Policy, Markets, and Bureaucracy: Reexamining School Choice , 1994, The Journal of Politics.

[18]  Mark Schneider,et al.  Networks to Nowhere: Segregation and Stratification in Networks of Information about Schools , 1997 .

[19]  C. Granger Investigating Causal Relations by Econometric Models and Cross-Spectral Methods , 1969 .

[20]  Gene V. Glass,et al.  Politics, Markets, and America's Schools , 1990 .

[21]  Jan E. Leighley,et al.  Race, Ethnicity, and Political Participation: Competing Models and Contrasting Explanations , 1999, The Journal of Politics.

[22]  Jonathan N. Katz,et al.  What To Do (and Not to Do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data , 1995, American Political Science Review.

[23]  C. Beard,et al.  The Case for Bureaucracy , 1986 .

[24]  C. Achilles,et al.  Class Size Does Make a Difference. , 1992 .

[25]  Sheila E. Murray,et al.  Schoolhouses, courthouses, and statehouses after Serrano , 1997 .

[26]  Larry V. Hedges,et al.  Have times changed?: The relation between school resources and student performance , 1996 .

[27]  E. Hanushek Expenditures, Efficiency, and Equity in Education: The Federal Government's Role , 1989 .

[28]  B. Wood Modeling Federal Implementation as a System: The Clean Air Case , 1992 .

[29]  Terry M. Moe,et al.  Politics, Markets, and the Organization of Schools , 1988, American Political Science Review.

[30]  J. Wortis,et al.  Privatization , 1988, Biological Psychiatry.

[31]  Mark Schneider,et al.  Shopping for Schools: In the Land of the Blind, The One-Eyed Parent May be Enough , 1998 .

[32]  Politics, Bureaucrats, and Schools. , 1994 .

[33]  Cheng Hsiao,et al.  Analysis of Panel Data , 1987 .

[34]  J. Bohte,et al.  School Bureaucracy and Student Performance at the Local Level , 2001 .

[35]  James D. Thompson Organizations in Action , 1967 .