A game theory based framework for assessing incentives for local area collaboration with an application to Scottish salmon farming.

Movements of water that transport pathogens mean that in net-pen aquaculture diseases are often most effectively managed collaboratively among neighbours. Such area management is widely and explicitly applied for pathogen management in marine salmon farms. Effective area management requires the active support of farm managers and a simple game-theory based framework was developed to identify the conditions required under which collaboration is perceived to be in their own best interest. The model applied is based on area management as practiced for Scottish salmon farms, but its simplicity allows it to be generalised to other area-managed net-pen aquaculture systems. In this model managers choose between purchasing tested pathogen-free fish or cheaper, untested fish that might carry pathogens. Perceived pay-off depends on degree of confidence that neighbours will not buy untested fish, risking input of pathogens that spread between farms. For a given level of risk, confidence in neighbours is most important in control of moderate-impact moderate-probability diseases. Common low-impact diseases require high confidence since there is a high probability a neighbour will import, while testing for rare high-impact diseases may be cost-effective regardless of neighbours actions. In some cases testing may be beneficial at an area level, even if all individual farms are better off not testing. Higher confidence is required for areas with many farms and so focusing management on smaller, epidemiologically imperfect, areas may be more effective. The confidence required for collaboration can be enhanced by the development of formal agreements and the involvement of outside disinterested parties such as trade bodies or government.

[1]  T. P. Adams,et al.  Connectivity modelling and network analysis of sea lice infection in Loch Fyne, west coast of Scotland , 2012 .

[2]  P. Jansen,et al.  Integration of hydrodynamics into a statistical model on the spread of pancreas disease (PD) in salmon farming. , 2009, Diseases of aquatic organisms.

[3]  A. Murray,et al.  Distribution of infectious pancreatic necrosis virus (IPNV) in wild marine fish from Scottish waters with respect to clinically infected aquaculture sites producing Atlantic salmon, Salmo salar L. , 2008, Journal of fish diseases.

[4]  B. D. Chang,et al.  Hydrographics and the timing of infectious salmon anemia outbreaks among Atlantic salmon (Salmo salar L.) farms in the Quoddy region of Maine, USA and New Brunswick, Canada. , 2007, Preventive veterinary medicine.

[5]  N. Salama,et al.  Developing models for investigating the environmental transmission of disease-causing agents within , 2013 .

[6]  M. Thrush,et al.  Epidemiology of Renibacterium salmoninarum in Scotland and the potential for compartmentalised management of salmon and trout farming areas , 2012 .

[7]  Wayne T. A. Enanoria,et al.  When Does Overuse of Antibiotics Become a Tragedy of the Commons? , 2012, PloS one.

[8]  C. Revie,et al.  Understanding sources of sea lice for salmon farms in Chile. , 2013, Preventive veterinary medicine.

[9]  Mark John Costello The global economic cost of sea lice to the salmonid farming industry. , 2009, Journal of fish diseases.

[10]  J. Nash,et al.  NON-COOPERATIVE GAMES , 1951, Classics in Game Theory.

[11]  Scott Barrett,et al.  Eradication versus control: the economics of global infectious disease policies. , 2004, Bulletin of the World Health Organization.

[12]  G. Gettinby,et al.  Identifying epidemiological factors affecting sea lice Lepeophtheirus salmonis abundance on Scottish salmon farms using general linear models. , 2003, Diseases of aquatic organisms.

[13]  T. Dempster,et al.  High connectivity of salmon farms revealed by aggregation, residence and repeated movements of wild fish among farms , 2009 .

[14]  J. Fraser,et al.  Development and assessment of a biophysical dispersal model for sea lice. , 2013, Journal of fish diseases.

[15]  J M Smith,et al.  Evolution and the theory of games , 1976 .

[16]  D. Earn,et al.  Vaccination and the theory of games. , 2004, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[17]  J. Romalde,et al.  A review of the main bacterial fish diseases in mariculture systems , 2005 .

[18]  A. Murray Epidemiology of the spread of viral diseases under aquaculture. , 2013, Current opinion in virology.

[19]  D. Green,et al.  The effectiveness of fallowing strategies in disease control in salmon aquaculture assessed with an SIS model. , 2011, Preventive veterinary medicine.

[20]  M. Milinski,et al.  Reputation helps solve the ‘tragedy of the commons’ , 2002, Nature.

[21]  M. Aldrin,et al.  Appendix to: Space-time modelling of the spread of salmon lice between and within Norwegian marine salmon farms , 2013 .

[22]  A. Murray,et al.  Epidemiological investigation into the re-emergence and control of an outbreak of infectious salmon anaemia in the Shetland Islands, Scotland. , 2010, Diseases of aquatic organisms.

[23]  Luiz Henrique Alves Monteiro,et al.  A vaccination game based on public health actions and personal decisions , 2011 .