Modeling the Transition to a New Economy: Lessons from Two Technological Revolutions

Many view the period after the Second Industrial Revolution as a paradigmatic example of a transition to a new economy following a technological revolution and conjecture that this historical experience is useful for understanding other transitions, including that after the Information Technology Revolution. We build a model of diffusion and growth to study transitions. We quantify the learning process in our model using data on the life cycle of U.S. manufacturing plants. This model accounts quantitatively for the productivity paradox, the slow diffusion of new technologies, and the ongoing investment in old technologies after the Second Industrial Revolution. The main lesson from our model for the Information Technology Revolution is that the nature of transition following a technological revolution depends on the historical context: transition and diffusion are slow only if agents have built up through learning a large amount of knowledge about old technologies before the transition begins.

[1]  N. Kiyotaki,et al.  Private sector development in transition economies , 1997 .

[2]  Varadarajan V. Chari,et al.  Vintage Human Capital, Growth, and the Diffusion of New Technology , 1991, Journal of Political Economy.

[3]  Philippe Aghion,et al.  On the Speed of Transition in Central Europe , 1994, NBER Macroeconomics Annual.

[4]  S. Sands Changes in Scale of Production in United States Manufacturing Industry, 1904-1947 , 1961 .

[5]  Jeffrey R. Campbell Computational Appendix to Entry, Exit, Embodied Technology, and Business Cycles , 1997 .

[6]  Miles S. Kimball,et al.  Cyclical Productivity with Unobserved Input Variation , 1997 .

[7]  M. Morton,et al.  The corporation of the 1990s: Information technology and organizational transformation , 1993 .

[8]  Jeffrey R. Campbell Entry, Exit, Embodied Technology, and Business Cycles , 1997 .

[9]  Linda Duxbury The corporation of the 1990s: Information technology and organizational transformation , 1993 .

[10]  Robert E. Lucas,et al.  On the Size Distribution of Business Firms , 1978 .

[11]  Boyan Jovanovic,et al.  General Purpose Technologies , 2005 .

[12]  John Laitner,et al.  Technological Change and the Stock Market , 2003 .

[13]  P. David The Dynamo and the Computer: An Historical Perspective on the Modern Productivity Paradox , 1990 .

[14]  Paul A. David,et al.  COMPUTER AND DYNAMO: The Modern Productivity Paradox in a Not-Too Distant Mirror , 1989 .

[15]  Scott D. Schuh,et al.  Job Creation and Destruction , 1997 .

[16]  Alfred D. Chandler Organizational Capabilities and the Economic History of the Industrial Enterprise , 1992 .

[17]  A. Atkeson,et al.  Industry evolution and transition: the role of information capital , 1993 .

[18]  A. Atkeson,et al.  Modeling and Measuring Organization Capital , 2005, Journal of Political Economy.

[19]  Ariel Pakes,et al.  The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry , 1996 .

[20]  H. E. Jones The replacement problem in child development. , 1956, Child development.

[21]  J. Mccombie,et al.  ‘Are There Laws of Production’: an assessment of the early criticisms of the , 1998 .

[22]  Erik Brynjolfsson,et al.  The Matrix of Change , 1997 .

[23]  Per Krusell,et al.  Can Technology Improvements Cause Productivity Slowdowns? , 1996, NBER Macroeconomics Annual.

[24]  Erik Brynjolfsson,et al.  Intangible Assets: Computers and Organizational Capital , 2002 .

[25]  Pietro Veronesi,et al.  Technological Revolutions and Stock Prices , 2005 .

[26]  Boyan Jovanovic,et al.  Entry, exit and diffusion with learning by doing , 1989 .

[27]  Douglas W. Dwyer,et al.  A Bayesian Learning Model Fitted to a Variety of Empirical Learning Curves , 1995 .

[28]  Micael Castanheira,et al.  The Optimal Speed of Transition: A General Equilibrium Analysis''CEPR Discussion Paper No , 2000 .

[29]  Nathan Rosenberg,et al.  On Technological Expectations , 1976 .

[30]  Horag Choi,et al.  Establishment Heterogeneity, Exporter Dynamics, and the Effects of Trade Liberalization , 2007 .

[31]  H. Stanley,et al.  On the Size Distribution of Business Firms , 2008 .

[32]  Gerard H. Kuper,et al.  Productivity, technology and economic growth , 2000 .

[33]  John G. Fernald,et al.  Are Apparent Productive Spillovers a Figment of Specification Error , 1994 .

[34]  Hernan J. Moscoso Boedo,et al.  Financial Structure, Informality and Development , 2012 .

[35]  R. Gordon Interpreting the "One Big Wave" in U.S. Long-Term Productivity Growth , 2000 .

[36]  Martin Neil Baily,et al.  Productivity Dynamics in Manufacturing Plants , 1992 .

[37]  Hugo Hopenhayn,et al.  Job Turnover and Policy Evaluation: A General Equilibrium Analysis , 1993, Journal of Political Economy.

[38]  Manuel Trajtenberg,et al.  Diffusion of General Purpose Technologies , 1996 .

[39]  Robert H. McGuckin,et al.  The Impact of Vintage and Survival on Productivity: Evidence from Cohorts of U.S. Manufacturing Plants , 2001, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[40]  Joseph Lerner,et al.  Energy in the American economy, 1850-1975 : an economic study of its history and prospects , 1961 .

[41]  Sam H. Schurr,et al.  Electricity in the American Economy: Agent of Technological Progress , 1990 .

[42]  Erik Brynjolfsson,et al.  The Matrix of Change: A Tool for Business Process Reengineering , 1996 .

[43]  A. Walters Production and Cost Functions: An Econometric Survey , 1963 .

[44]  W. Devine,et al.  From Shafts to Wires: Historical Perspective on Electrification , 1983, The Journal of Economic History.

[45]  A. Pakes,et al.  The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry , 1992 .

[46]  P. Howitt,et al.  Endogenous Growth Theory , 1999 .

[47]  Eric J. Bartelsman,et al.  Productivity Dynamics: U.S. Manufacturing Plants, 1972–1986 , 1999 .

[48]  Esteban Rossi-Hansberg,et al.  Spatial Growth and Industry Age , 2007, J. Econ. Theory.

[49]  Michael Gort,et al.  Decomposing Learning by Doing in New Plants , 1993, Journal of Political Economy.

[50]  L. Ohanian,et al.  Are data on industry evolution and gross job turnover relevant for macroeconomics , 1996 .

[51]  Are There Laws , 1998 .

[52]  L. Argote,et al.  Learning Curves in Manufacturing , 1990, Science.

[53]  Paul A. David,et al.  General Purpose Technologies and Surges in Productivity: Historical Reflections on the Future of the ICT Revolution , 1999 .

[54]  M. Baddeley Structural Shifts in UK Unemployment 1979-2005: The Twin Impacts of Financial Deregulation and Computerization , 2008 .

[55]  Susanto Basu,et al.  Procyclical Productivity: Increasing Returns or Cyclical Utilization? , 1995 .

[56]  Thomas Weiss,et al.  The Regional Diffusion and Adoption of the Steam Engine in American Manufacturing , 1980, The Journal of Economic History.

[57]  Boyan Jovanovic Selection and the evolution of industry , 1981 .

[58]  E. Brynjolfsson,et al.  Beyond Computation: Information Technology, Organizational Transformation and Business Performance , 2000 .