Paying Not to Go to the Gym

How do consumers choose from a menu of contracts? We analyze a novel dataset from three U.S. health clubs with information on both the contractual choice and the day-to-day attendance decisions of 7,752 members over three years. The observed consumer behavior is difficult to reconcile with standard preferences and beliefs. First, members who choose a contract with a flat monthly fee of over $70 attend on average 4.3 times per month. They pay a price per expected visit of more than $17, even though they could pay $10 per visit using a 10-visit pass. On average, these users forgo savings of $600 during their membership. Second, consumers who choose a monthly contract are 17 percent more likely to stay enrolled beyond one year than users committing for a year. This is surprising because monthly members pay higher fees for the option to cancel each month. We also document cancellation delays and attendance expectations, among other findings. Leading explanations for our findings are overconfidence about future self-control or about future efficiency. Overconfident agents overestimate attendance as well as the cancellation probability of automatically renewed contracts. Our results suggest that making inferences from observed contract choice under the rational expectation hypothesis can lead to biases in the estimation of consumer preferences. (JEL D00, D12, D91)

[1]  R. H. Strotz Myopia and Inconsistency in Dynamic Utility Maximization , 1955 .

[2]  R. Pollak,et al.  SECOND-BEST NATIONAL SAVING AND GAME-EQUILIBRIUM GROWTH , 1980 .

[3]  George Hendrikse,et al.  The Theory of Industrial Organization , 1989 .

[4]  George A. Akerlof Procrastination and Obedience , 1991 .

[5]  B. Bernheim,et al.  A Theory of Conformity , 1994, Journal of Political Economy.

[6]  H. Fielding Bridget Jones: The Edge of Reason , 1996 .

[7]  David I. Laibson,et al.  Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting , 1997 .

[8]  H. Fielding Bridget Jones's diary : a novel , 1998 .

[9]  Drazen Prelec,et al.  The Red and the Black: Mental Accounting of Savings and Debt , 1998 .

[10]  John T. Gourville,et al.  Payment Depreciation: The Behavioral Effects of Temporally Separating Payments from Consumption , 1998 .

[11]  Ted O’Donoghue,et al.  Doing It Now or Later , 1999 .

[12]  Matthew Rabin,et al.  Choice and Procrastination , 2000 .

[13]  M. Rabin Risk Aversion and Expected Utility Theory: A Calibration Theorem , 2000 .

[14]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Projection Bias in Predicting Future Utility , 2000 .

[15]  Stefano DellaVigna,et al.  Overestimating Self-Control: Evidence from the Health Club Industry , 2002 .

[16]  Ulrike Malmendier,et al.  Contract Design and Self-Control: Theory and Evidence , 2004 .

[17]  Eugenio J. Miravete Choosing the Wrong Calling Plan? Ignorance and Learning , 2003 .

[18]  M. Paserman Job Search and Hyperbolic Discounting: Structural Estimation and Policy Evaluation , 2004, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[19]  David Laibson,et al.  Estimating Discount Functions from Lifecycle Consumption Choices , 2004 .

[20]  Kfir Eliaz,et al.  Contracting with Diversely Naive Agents , 2004 .

[21]  Lawrence M. Ausubel,et al.  Time Inconsistency in the Credit Card Market , 2004 .

[22]  B. Kőszegi,et al.  The Impact of Consumer Loss Aversion on Pricing , 2004 .

[23]  I. Hendel,et al.  Intertemporal Substitution and Storable Products , 2004 .

[24]  Glenn Ellison Bounded Rationality in Industrial Organization , 2005 .

[25]  D. Fudenberg Advancing Beyond Advances in Behavioral Economics , 2006 .

[26]  Qi Li Nonparametric econometrics , 2006 .

[27]  Alois Stutzer,et al.  Active Decisions and Prosocial Behaviour: A Field Experiment on Blood Donation , 2011 .

[28]  P. Grauwe,et al.  The Exchange Rate in a Behavioral Finance Framework , 2006 .

[29]  Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts? , 2006 .

[30]  Marco Casari,et al.  Pre-commitment and flexibility in a time decision experiment , 2006 .

[31]  Glenn Ellison,et al.  Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Bounded Rationality in Industrial Organization , 2006 .

[32]  Ted O'Donoghue,et al.  Projection Bias in Catalog Orders , 2007 .

[33]  Steven D. Levitt,et al.  Viewpoint: On the Generalizability of Lab Behaviour to the Field , 2007 .

[34]  José A. Ordaz Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Ninth World Congress , 2007, Technometrics.

[35]  Andy Kay Edge of reason , 2007 .

[36]  B. Frey,et al.  Does Watching TV Make Us Happy? , 2005 .

[37]  Ernesto Reuben,et al.  credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Procrastination and Impatience , 2007 .

[38]  Chris M. Wilson,et al.  Do Consumers Switch to the Best Supplier? , 2007 .

[39]  Peter Kooreman,et al.  What Does Behavioral Economics Mean for Policy? Challenges to Savings and Health Policies in the Netherlands , 2010 .

[40]  G. Berns,et al.  Intertemporal choice – toward an integrative framework , 2007, Trends in Cognitive Sciences.

[41]  David Laibson,et al.  Estimating Discount Functions with Consumption Choices Over the Lifecycle , 2007 .

[42]  Steven D. Levitt,et al.  What Do Laboratory Experiments Measuring Social Preferences Reveal About the Real World , 2007 .

[43]  Katherine L. Milkman,et al.  Harnessing Our Inner Angels and Demons: What We Have Learned About Want/Should Conflicts and How That Knowledge Can Help Us Reduce Short-Sighted Decision Making , 2008, Perspectives on psychological science : a journal of the Association for Psychological Science.

[44]  Nicholas Economides,et al.  Quantifying the Benefits of Entry into Local Phone Service , 2006 .