Market targeting with social influences and risk aversion in a co-branding alliance

Abstract We consider a fast-fashion brand that cooperates with a luxury brand, jointly launching a co-branded product. The impacts of the co-branding on the two brands’ original product lines are uncertain, and each brand can be either risk averse or risk neutral. Consumers, driven by exclusivity or conformity, are classified as either snobs or conformists. The equilibrium retail price, quality investment, and investment support are derived. The optimal market-targeting strategy for the fast-fashion brand as marketer of the co-branded product, is identified. We show that the fast-fashion brand is willing to give up either the conformist or the snob market under certain conditions, even when it has sales in both markets. In addition, given a particular market-targeting strategy, the fast-fashion brand benefits from its own risk aversion if the cost of risk is low, but the luxury brand is always worse off; the luxury brand may benefit from the fast-fashion brand’s risk aversion, however, if the market-targeting strategy is changed. Both brands are worse off when the luxury brand is risk averse.

[1]  Weihua Liu,et al.  Service order allocation under uncertain demand: Risk aversion, peer competition, and relationship strength , 2019, Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review.

[2]  Wilfred Amaldoss,et al.  Pricing of Conspicuous Goods: A Competitive Analysis of Social Effects , 2005 .

[3]  Na Liu,et al.  Optimal Pricing, Modularity, and Return Policy Under Mass Customization , 2012, IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics - Part A: Systems and Humans.

[4]  Ahmad Jamal,et al.  Collaborating for success: managerial perspectives on co-branding strategies in the fashion industry , 2014 .

[5]  Gema Vinuales,et al.  Understanding the role of social influence in piquing curiosity and influencing attitudes and behaviors in a social network environment , 2017 .

[6]  C. Whan Park,et al.  Composite Branding Alliances: An Investigation of Extension and Feedback Effects , 1996 .

[7]  Robert P. Leone,et al.  Implicit Price Bundling of Retail Products: A Multiproduct Approach to Maximizing Store Profitability , 1991 .

[8]  Tian Bai,et al.  Pricing and ordering by a loss averse newsvendor with reference dependence , 2019, Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review.

[9]  Jennifer J. Argo,et al.  Social Influence in the Retail Context: A Contemporary Review of the Literature , 2020 .

[10]  Nick Russell,et al.  Co-branding — the science of alliance , 1999 .

[11]  Maqbool Dada,et al.  Pricing and the Newsvendor Problem: A Review with Extensions , 1999, Oper. Res..

[12]  U. Okonkwo,et al.  Luxury Fashion Branding: Trends, Tactics, Techniques , 2007 .

[13]  Tsan-Ming Choi,et al.  Optimal Advertising and Pricing Strategies for Luxury Fashion Brands With Social Influences , 2012, IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics - Part A: Systems and Humans.

[14]  Peter E. Rossi,et al.  Determinants of Store-Level Price Elasticity , 1995 .

[15]  Shu Guo,et al.  Green product development under competition: A study of the fashion apparel industry , 2020, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[16]  M. Farah,et al.  From Karl Lagerfeld to Erdem: a series of collaborations between designer luxury brands and fast-fashion brands , 2019, Journal of Brand Management.

[17]  W. Tsai,et al.  Young Chinese Consumers’ Snob and Bandwagon Luxury Consumption Preferences , 2013 .

[18]  Raoul V. Kübler,et al.  The Role of the Partner Brand's Social Media Power in Brand Alliances , 2018 .

[19]  T. Choi,et al.  Brand loyalties in designer luxury and fast fashion co-branding alliances , 2017 .

[20]  Tsan-Ming Choi,et al.  Optimal Advertising Budget Allocation in Luxury Fashion Markets with Social Influences: A Mean-Variance Analysis , 2018, Production and Operations Management.

[21]  Chun-Hung Chiu,et al.  Store brand introduction in a two-echelon logistics system with a risk-averse retailer , 2016 .

[22]  Xueping Zhen,et al.  The Effects of Herding and Word of Mouth in a Two-Period Advertising Signaling Model , 2018, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[23]  C. Benedetto,et al.  The Impact of Luxury Brand-Retailer Co-Branding Strategy on Consumers’ Evaluation of Luxury Brand Image: The Case of Taiwan , 2012 .

[24]  Christopher S. Tang,et al.  Entry of Copycats of Luxury Brands , 2017, Mark. Sci..

[25]  T. Choi,et al.  Optimal pricing in mass customization supply chains with risk-averse agents and retail competition , 2019, Omega.

[26]  F. Völckner,et al.  Drivers of Brand Extension Success , 2006 .

[27]  Wansheng Tang,et al.  Should a manufacturer give up pricing power in a vertical information-sharing channel? , 2019, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[28]  Tsan-Ming Choi,et al.  Selling luxury fashion online with social influences considerations: Demand changes and supply chain coordination , 2017 .

[29]  Tsan-Ming Choi,et al.  Supply chain risk analysis with mean-variance models: a technical review , 2016, Ann. Oper. Res..

[30]  Tansev Geylani,et al.  Image Reinforcement or Impairment: The Effects of Co-Branding on Attribute Uncertainty , 2008, Mark. Sci..

[31]  Wilfred Amaldoss,et al.  Conspicuous Consumption and Sophisticated Thinking , 2005, Manag. Sci..

[32]  Peter S. H. Leeflang,et al.  Co-branding: The State of the Art , 2008 .

[33]  Wilfred Amaldoss,et al.  Branding Conspicuous Goods: An Analysis of the Effects of Social Influence and Competition , 2015, Manag. Sci..

[34]  Sujuan Wang,et al.  Contract type and decision right of sales promotion in supply chain management with a capital constrained retailer , 2015, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[35]  Hjp Harry Timmermans,et al.  Investigating heterogeneity in social influence by social distance in car-sharing decisions under uncertainty: A regret-minimizing hybrid choice model framework based on sequential stated adaptation experiments☆ , 2016 .

[36]  Randi Priluck,et al.  Brand alliance and customer-based brand-equity effects , 2004 .

[37]  G. Zaccour,et al.  Optimal quality improvements and pricing strategies with active and passive product returns , 2019, Omega.

[38]  T. C. Edwin Cheng,et al.  Quick Response in Supply Chains with Stochastically Risk Sensitive Retailers , 2018, Decis. Sci..

[39]  Jun Zhang,et al.  Impacts of Power Structure on Supply Chains with Uncertain Demand , 2013 .

[40]  Hon-Shiang Lau The Newsboy Problem under Alternative Optimization Objectives , 1980 .

[41]  Irwin P. Levin,et al.  Modeling the Role of Brand Alliances in the Assimilation of Product Evaluations , 2000 .

[42]  A. Stuart,et al.  Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments , 1959 .

[43]  Wuyi Yue,et al.  Quality investment and price decision in a risk-averse supply chain , 2011, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[44]  Ariel Rubinstein,et al.  A Course in Game Theory , 1995 .

[45]  Bernard L. Simonin,et al.  Is a Company Known by the Company it Keeps? Assessing the Spillover Effects of Brand Alliances on Consumer Brand Attitudes , 1998 .

[46]  H. Unnava,et al.  Spillover of Negative Information on Brand Alliances , 2006 .

[47]  Honglin Yang,et al.  Mean-variance analysis of option contracts in a two-echelon supply chain , 2018, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[48]  Chiranjeev Kohli,et al.  2+2=5? A framework for using co-branding to leverage a brand , 2003 .

[49]  Melike Baykal-Gursoy,et al.  Mean-variance analysis of the newsvendor problem with price-dependent, isoelastic demand , 2020, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[50]  G. Zaccour,et al.  Market targeting and information sharing with social influences in a luxury supply chain , 2020 .

[51]  L. Beril Toktay,et al.  The Limits of Planned Obsolescence for Conspicuous Durable Goods , 2015, Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag..