The Effect of Ostracism and Optional Participation on the Evolution of Cooperation in the Voluntary Public Goods Game

Not only animals, plants and microbes but also humans cooperate in groups. The evolution of cooperation in a group is an evolutionary puzzle, because defectors always obtain a higher benefit than cooperators. When people participate in a group, they evaluate group member’s reputations and then decide whether to participate in it. In some groups, membership is open to all who are willing to participate in the group. In other groups, a candidate is excluded from membership if group members regard the candidate’s reputation as bad. We developed an evolutionary game model and investigated how participation in groups and ostracism influence the evolution of cooperation in groups when group members play the voluntary public goods game, by means of computer simulation. When group membership is open to all candidates and those candidates can decide whether to participate in a group, cooperation cannot be sustainable. However, cooperation is sustainable when a candidate cannot be a member unless all group members admit them to membership. Therefore, it is not participation in a group but rather ostracism, which functions as costless punishment on defectors, that is essential to sustain cooperation in the voluntary public goods game.

[1]  Mitsuhiro Nakamura,et al.  Groupwise information sharing promotes ingroup favoritism in indirect reciprocity , 2012, BMC Evolutionary Biology.

[2]  L. Dugatkin,et al.  Group Selection and Assortative Interactions , 1997, The American Naturalist.

[3]  Subramanian Ramamoorthy Games, Groups and the Global Good , 2013, J. Oper. Res. Soc..

[4]  H. Gintis,et al.  The evolution of strong reciprocity: cooperation in heterogeneous populations. , 2004, Theoretical population biology.

[5]  H. Ohtsuki,et al.  A simple rule for the evolution of cooperation on graphs and social networks , 2006, Nature.

[6]  C. Hauert,et al.  Reward and punishment , 2001, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[7]  Marcus W. Feldman,et al.  Cultural Transmission and Evolution (MPB-16), Volume 16: A Quantitative Approach. (MPB-16) , 1981 .

[8]  Yoh Iwasa,et al.  The coevolution of altruism and punishment: role of the selfish punisher. , 2006, Journal of theoretical biology.

[9]  L. Giraldeau,et al.  Food exploitation: searching for the optimal joining policy. , 1999, Trends in ecology & evolution.

[10]  R. Axelrod An Evolutionary Approach to Norms , 1986, American Political Science Review.

[11]  M. Nakamaru,et al.  Evolution of cooperation in rotating indivisible goods game. , 2010, Journal of theoretical biology.

[12]  M. Feldman,et al.  Cultural transmission and evolution: a quantitative approach. , 1981, Monographs in population biology.

[13]  Yen-Sheng Chiang A Path Toward Fairness , 2008 .

[14]  R. Sugden The Economics of Rights, Co-Operation, and Welfare , 1986 .

[15]  B. Armendáriz,et al.  The Economics of Microfinance , 2006 .

[16]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Reward and cooperation in the spatial public goods game , 2010, ArXiv.

[17]  Henry F. Lyle,et al.  The reputational and social network benefits of prosociality in an Andean community , 2014, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[18]  María Soledad Martínez Pería The economics of microfinance , 2006 .

[19]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Evolutionary advantages of adaptive rewarding , 2012, 1208.3457.

[20]  M N,et al.  The Evolution of Cooperation in a Lattice-Structured Population , 1996 .

[21]  Karl Sigmund,et al.  The competition of assessment rules for indirect reciprocity. , 2010, Journal of theoretical biology.

[22]  C. Hauert,et al.  Replicator dynamics for optional public good games. , 2002, Journal of theoretical biology.

[23]  Tatsuya Sasaki,et al.  The evolution of cooperation by social exclusion , 2012, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[24]  J. Strassmann,et al.  Evolution of microbial markets , 2014, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[25]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring , 1998, Nature.

[26]  G. Brady Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action , 1993 .

[27]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Climate policies under wealth inequality , 2014, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[28]  Yoh Iwasa,et al.  How should we define goodness?--reputation dynamics in indirect reciprocity. , 2004, Journal of theoretical biology.

[29]  Eizo Akiyama,et al.  Reputation and the evolution of cooperation in sizable groups , 2005, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[30]  M. Milinski,et al.  Volunteering leads to rock–paper–scissors dynamics in a public goods game , 2003, Nature.

[31]  S. De Monte,et al.  GROUP FORMATION AND THE EVOLUTION OF SOCIALITY , 2013, Evolution; international journal of organic evolution.

[32]  C. Hauert,et al.  Via Freedom to Coercion: The Emergence of Costly Punishment , 2007, Science.

[33]  Sandra L. Vehrencamp,et al.  A model for the evolution of despotic versus egalitarian societies , 1983, Animal Behaviour.

[34]  W. Kilmer,et al.  INTERDEMIC SELECTION AND THE EVOLUTION OF ALTRUISM: A COMPUTER SIMULATION STUDY , 1974, Evolution; international journal of organic evolution.

[35]  Robb Willer,et al.  Gossip and Ostracism Promote Cooperation in Groups , 2014, Psychological science.

[36]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Phase Diagrams for the Spatial Public Goods Game with Pool-Punishment , 2011, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[37]  R. Riolo,et al.  Evolution of cooperation without reciprocity , 2001, Nature.

[38]  P. Richerson,et al.  The evolution of reciprocity in sizable groups. , 1988, Journal of theoretical biology.

[39]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary games and spatial chaos , 1992, Nature.

[40]  S. Levin,et al.  Regime shifts in a social-ecological system , 2013, Theoretical Ecology.

[41]  W. Hamilton,et al.  The evolution of cooperation. , 1984, Science.

[42]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Evolutionary Establishment of Moral and Double Moral Standards through Spatial Interactions , 2010, PLoS Comput. Biol..

[43]  Maja Schlüter,et al.  The Survival of the Conformist: Social Pressure and Renewable Resource Management , 2010, Journal of theoretical biology.

[44]  C. Geertz,et al.  The Rotating Credit Association: A "Middle Rung" in Development , 1962, Economic Development and Cultural Change.

[45]  I. Couzin,et al.  Effective leadership and decision-making in animal groups on the move , 2005, Nature.

[46]  W. Hamilton The genetical evolution of social behaviour. I. , 1964, Journal of theoretical biology.

[47]  I. Mysterud Unto others: The evolution and psychology of unselfish behavior , 1999 .

[48]  V. Isaeva Self-organization in biological systems , 2012, Biology Bulletin.

[49]  C. Hauert,et al.  Volunteering as Red Queen Mechanism for Cooperation in Public Goods Games , 2002, Science.

[50]  F. Maier-Rigaud,et al.  Ostracism and the Provision of a Public Good: Experimental Evidence , 2009 .

[51]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Correlation of positive and negative reciprocity fails to confer an evolutionary advantage: Phase transitions to elementary strategies , 2013, ArXiv.

[52]  Dirk Helbing,et al.  Social Self-Organization , 2012 .

[53]  C Athena Aktipis,et al.  Know when to walk away: contingent movement and the evolution of cooperation. , 2004, Journal of theoretical biology.