Politics and Economics of Second-Best Regulation of Greenhouse Gases: The Importance of Regulatory Credibility

Modellers have examined a wide array of ideal-world scenarios for regulation of greenhouse gases. In this ideal world, all countries limit emissions from all economic sectors; regulations are implemented by intelligent, well-informed forward-looking agents; all abatement options, such as new energy technologies and forestry offsets, are available; trade in goods, services and emission credits is free and unfettered. Here we systematically explore more plausible second-best worlds. While analysts have given inordinate attention to which countries participate in regulation—what we call “variable geometry”—which has a strikingly small impact on total world cost of carbon regulations if international trade in emission credits allows economies to equilibrate. Limits on emission trading raise those costs, but by a much smaller amount than expected because even modest amounts of emission trading (less than 15% of abatement in a plausible scenario that varies the geometry of effort) have a large cost-reducing impact. Second best scenarios that see one sector regulated more aggressively and rapidly than others do not impose much extra burden when compared with optimal all-sector scenarios provided that regulations begin in the power sector. Indeed, some forms of trade regulation might decrease the financial flows associated to a carbon policy thus increasing political feasibility of the climate agreement. Much more important than variable geometry, trading and sectors is another factor that analysts have largely ignored: credibility. In the real world governments find it difficult to craft and implement credible international regulations and thus agents are unable to be so forward-looking as assumed in ideal-world modelling exercises. As credibility declines the cost of coordinated international regulation skyrockets—even in developing countries that are likely to delay their adoption of binding limits on emissions. Because international institutions such as treaties are usually weak, governments must rely on their own actions to boost regulatory credibility—for example, governments might “pre-commit” international regulations into domestic law before international negotiations are finally settled, thus boosting credibility. In our scenarios, China alone would be a net beneficiary of pre-commitment that advances its carbon limits two decades (from 2030, in our scenario, to today) if doing so would make international regulations more credible and thus encourage Chinese firms to invest with a clearer eye to the future. Overall, low credibility is up to 6 times more important in driving higher world costs for carbon regulations when compared with variable geometry, limits on emission trading and variable sectors. In this paper, we have not explored the other major dimension to the second-best: the lack of timely availability of the full range of abatement options, although our results suggest that even this will be less consequential than credibility.

[1]  E. Penrose Sovereignty at Bay: The Multinational Spread of U.S. Enterprises . By Raymond Vernon. New York, Basic Books, 1971. Pp. x + 236. $8.50. , 1972, Business History Review.

[2]  Akihiro Sawa A Sectoral Approach as an Option for a Post-Kyoto Framework The Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements , 2008 .

[3]  M. Moretto,et al.  Licences, 'Use or Lose' Provisions and the Time of Investment , 2010 .

[4]  F. Bosello Adaptation, Mitigation and 'Green' R&D to Combat Global Climate Change - Insights from an Empirical Integrated Assessment Exercise , 2008 .

[5]  A. Chayes,et al.  The New Sovereignty , 1995 .

[6]  Edward A. Parson,et al.  Protecting the Ozone Layer , 2003 .

[7]  Robert O. Keohane,et al.  After Hegemony , 2005 .

[8]  A. Rodríguez‐Pose,et al.  Returns to Migration, Education, and Externalities in the European Union , 2010 .

[9]  Alice Favero,et al.  Fairness, Credibility, and Effectiveness in the Copenhagen Accord: An Economic Assessment , 2010 .

[10]  A. C. Coolidge,et al.  Foreign affairs (Council on Foreign Relations) , 1922 .

[11]  Carlo Giupponi,et al.  A Participatory Approach to Assess the Effectiveness of Responses to Cope with Flood Risk , 2010 .

[12]  Carlo Carraro,et al.  Modeling Biased Technical Change - Implications for Climate Policy , 2010 .

[13]  Valentina Bosetti,et al.  Climate Change Mitigation Strategies in Fast-Growing Countries: The Benefits of Early Action , 2009, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[14]  Carlo Giupponi,et al.  Potentials and Limits of Bayesian Networks to Deal with Uncertainty in the Assessment of Climate Change Adaptation Policies , 2010 .

[15]  David G. Victor,et al.  Climate Change and the Energy Challenge: A Pragmatic Approach for India , 2009 .

[16]  L. Clarke,et al.  International climate policy architectures: Overview of the EMF 22 International Scenarios , 2009 .

[17]  Alice Favero,et al.  Investments and Financial Flows Induced by Climate Mitigation Policies , 2010 .

[18]  E. Woodhouse The Obsolescing Bargain Redux? Foreign Investment in the Electric Power Sector in Developing Countries , 2005 .

[19]  T. Schelling The Strategy of Conflict , 1963 .

[20]  C. Cattaneo Migrants’ International Transfers and Educational Expenditure: Empirical Evidence from Albania , 2010 .

[21]  R. Vernon Sovereignty at bay: The multinational spread of U.S. enterprises , 1971 .

[22]  Valentina Bosetti,et al.  Delayed Participation of Developing Countries to Climate Agreements: Should Action in the EU and US Be Postponed? , 2008, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[23]  Shilpa Rao,et al.  International climate regimes: effects of delayed participation , 2007 .

[24]  Sergey Paltsev,et al.  The cost of climate policy in the United States , 2009 .

[25]  Valentina Bosetti,et al.  Modelling Economic Impacts of Alternative International Climate Policy Architectures: A Quantitative and Comparative Assessment of Architectures for Agreement , 2008, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[26]  Andrew T. Guzman How International Law Works , 2008 .

[27]  S. Paltsev,et al.  Sharing the Burden of GHG Reductions , 2008 .

[28]  Robert Stavins,et al.  Linkage of Tradable Permit Systems in International Climate Policy Architecture , 2008 .

[29]  A. Krajnc,et al.  The Collapse of the Kyoto Protocol and the Struggle to Slow Global Warming , 2003 .

[30]  T. Rutherford,et al.  Feasible climate targets: The roles of economic growth, coalition development and expectations ☆ , 2009 .

[31]  Carlo Scarpa,et al.  Do Competition and Ownership Matter? Evidence from Local Public Transport in Europe , 2010 .

[32]  Gernot Wagner,et al.  Docking into a global carbon market: Clean Investment Budgets to encourage emerging economy participation , 2009 .

[33]  Valentina Bosetti,et al.  The 2008 Witch Model: New Model Features and Baseline , 2009 .

[34]  A. Ellerman,et al.  Allocation in the European Emissions Trading Scheme , 2007 .

[35]  A. Petrucci Second-Best Optimal Taxation of Oil and Capital in a Small Open Economy , 2010 .

[36]  T. Rutherford,et al.  International climate policy: a “second best” solution for a “second best” world? , 2009 .

[37]  M. Tavoni,et al.  The Role of International Carbon Offsets in a Second-Best Climate Policy: A Numerical Evaluation , 2010 .

[38]  Joseph E. Aldy,et al.  The Competitiveness Impacts of Climate Change Mitigation Policies , 2011, Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists.

[39]  J. Wagner Ozone diplomacy: new directions in safeguarding the planet , 1992 .

[40]  Georg Umgiesser,et al.  An Economic Assessment of the Impacts of the Mose Barriers on Venice Port Activities , 2010 .

[41]  William Oduro,et al.  Changes in Beliefs and Perceptions About the Natural Environment in the Forest-Savanna Transitional Zone of Ghana: The Influence of Religion , 2010 .

[42]  David M. Rocke,et al.  Tacit bargaining, arms races, and arms control , 1990 .

[43]  Condoleezza Rice,et al.  Promoting the National Interest , 2000 .

[44]  E. Posner,et al.  The Limits of International Law , 2005 .

[45]  R. Benedick Ozone Diplomacy: New Directions in Safeguarding the Planet , 1991 .

[46]  M. Kahler Multilateralism with small and large numbers , 1992, International Organization.

[47]  J. Edmonds,et al.  Stabilizing CO2 concentrations with incomplete international cooperation , 2008 .

[48]  Richard Monastersky,et al.  Climate crunch: A burden beyond bearing , 2009, Nature.

[49]  M. Tavoni,et al.  A World Induced Technical Change Hybrid Model , 2006 .

[50]  D. Victor,et al.  The Political Economy of Power Sector Reform: The Experiences of Five Major Developing Countries , 2009 .

[51]  David G. Victor,et al.  A Madisonian Approach to Climate Policy , 2005, Science.

[52]  Luca Di Corato,et al.  Profit Sharing under the Threat of Nationalization , 2013 .

[53]  W. Nordhaus Life after Kyoto: Alternative Approaches to Global Warming , 2005 .

[54]  Makoto Okamura,et al.  Optimal Emission Tax with Endogenous Location Choice of Duopolistic Firms , 2009 .

[55]  Asami Miketa,et al.  The impact of R&D on innovation for wind energy in Denmark, Germany and the United Kingdom , 2005 .

[56]  James K. Sebenius,et al.  Negotiating the Law of the Sea , 1984 .

[57]  Stelios Kafandaris,et al.  Buying Greenhouse Insurance: The Economic Costs of CO2 Emission Limits , 1992 .

[58]  Linkage of Tradable Permit Systems in International Climate Policy Architecture , 2008 .

[59]  T. Schelling,et al.  The Strategy of Conflict. , 1961 .

[60]  A. Jaffe,et al.  A tale of two market failures: Technology and environmental policy , 2005 .

[61]  David W. Keith,et al.  Carbon Capture Retrofits and the Cost of Regulatory Uncertainty , 2007, The Energy Journal.

[62]  S. Isoard,et al.  Endogenous learning in world post-Kyoto scenarios: application of the POLES model under adaptive expectations , 2000 .