On Measuring the Welfare Cost of Business Cycles

Lucas (1987) argues that the gain from eliminating aggregate fluctuations is trivial. Following Lucas, a number of researchers have altered assumptions on preferences and found that the gain from eliminating business cycles are potentially very large. However, in these exercises little discipline is placed on preference parameters. This paper estimates the welfare cost of business cycles, allowing for potential time-non-separabilities in preferences, where discipline is placed on the choice of preference parameters by requiring that the preferences be consistent with observed fluctuations in a model of business cycles. That is, a theoretical real business cycle world is constructed and the representative agent is then placed in this world. The agent responds optimally to exogenous shocks, given the frictions in the economy. The agent's preference parameters, along with other structural parameters, are estimated using a Bayesian procedure involving Markov Chain Monte Carlo methods. Two main results emerge from the paper. First, the form for the time-non-separability estimated in this paper is very different than the forms suggested and used elsewhere in the literature. Second, the welfare cost of business cycles is close to Lucas's estimate.

[1]  K. Rouwenhorst Time to build and aggregate fluctuations: A reconsideration , 1991 .

[2]  Yi Wen,et al.  Can a real business cycle model pass the Watson test , 1998 .

[3]  Russell Cooper,et al.  Dynamic Complementarities: A Quantitative Analysis , 1996 .

[4]  L. Tierney Markov Chains for Exploring Posterior Distributions , 1994 .

[5]  Thomas D. Tallarini Risk-sensitive real business cycles☆ , 2000 .

[6]  R. King,et al.  Chapter 14 Resuscitating real business cycles , 1999 .

[7]  Russell Cooper,et al.  Evidence on Macroeconomic Complementarities , 1993 .

[8]  Timothy Cogley,et al.  Output Dynamics in Real-Business-Cycle Models , 1993 .

[9]  J. Pemberton Growth trends, cyclical fluctuations, and welfare with non-expected utility preferences , 1996 .

[10]  J. Geweke,et al.  Bayesian Inference in Econometric Models Using Monte Carlo Integration , 1989 .

[11]  Beth F. Ingram,et al.  A Bayesian approach to dynamic macroeconomics , 2000 .

[12]  Christopher D. Carroll,et al.  Comparison Utility in a Growth Model , 1997 .

[13]  Siddhartha Chib,et al.  Markov Chain Monte Carlo Simulation Methods in Econometrics , 1996, Econometric Theory.

[14]  Mark A. Wynne,et al.  The role of intratemporal adjustment costs in a multisector economy , 1999 .

[15]  S. Rebelo,et al.  Resuscitating Real Business Cycles , 2000 .

[16]  Richard Rogerson,et al.  Indivisible labor, lotteries and equilibrium , 1988 .

[17]  Jonathan D. Cryer,et al.  Time Series Analysis , 1986 .

[18]  Charles I. Plosser,et al.  Production, growth and business cycles , 1988 .

[19]  Lawrence J. Christiano,et al.  Small Sample Properties of GMM for Business Cycle Analysis , 1995 .

[20]  John Y. Campbell,et al.  Asset Prices, Consumption, and the Business Cycle , 1998 .

[21]  Christopher D. Carroll,et al.  Saving and Growth with Habit Formation , 2000 .

[22]  David N. DeJong,et al.  The Cyclical Behavior of Skill Acquisition , 2001 .

[23]  Andrew B. Abel,et al.  Asset Prices Under Habit Formation and Catching Up with the Joneses , 1990 .

[24]  J. Campbell,et al.  By Force of Habit: A Consumption‐Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.

[25]  Finn E. Kydland,et al.  Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations , 1982 .

[26]  Marianne Baxter,et al.  Measuring Business Cycles: Approximate Band-Pass Filters for Economic Time Series , 1995, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[27]  Plutarchos Sakellaris,et al.  Human capital formation and business cycle persistence , 1998 .

[28]  G. Hansen Indivisible Labor and the Business Cycle , 1985 .

[29]  Jeremy Greenwood,et al.  Investment, Capacity Utilization and the Real Business Cycle , 1988 .

[30]  Eric van Wincoop,et al.  Welfare gains from international risksharing , 1994 .

[31]  R. Thaler,et al.  Myopic Loss Aversion and the Equity Premium Puzzle , 1993 .

[32]  Charles I. Plosser,et al.  Growth and Business Cycles I. The Basic Neoclassical Model , 1988 .

[33]  R. Lucas Studies in business-cycle theory , 1987 .

[34]  Garey Ramey,et al.  Cross-Country Evidence on the Link between Volatility and Growth , 1994 .

[35]  David M. Kreps,et al.  Advances In Economics and Econometrics: Theory And Applications: Seventh World Congress , 1997 .

[36]  Martin Eichenbaum,et al.  Factor Hoarding and the Propagation of Business Cycles Shocks , 1994 .

[37]  Arthur F. Burns,et al.  Measuring Business Cycles. , 1946 .

[38]  C. Whiteman,et al.  Keynesian Impulses Versus Solow Residuals: Identifying Sources of Business Cycle Fluctuations , 2000 .

[39]  M. Obstfeld Evaluating Risky Consumption Paths: the Role of Intertemporal Substitutability , 1994 .

[40]  Andrew B. Abel,et al.  Risk Premia and Term Premia in General Equilibrium , 1998 .

[41]  Urban Jermann Asset pricing in production economies , 1998 .

[42]  Randall Wright,et al.  Homework in Macroeconomics: Household Production and Aggregate Fluctuations , 1991, Journal of Political Economy.

[43]  Christopher C. Otrok,et al.  Spectral Welfare Cost Functions , 2001 .

[44]  M. Watson Measures of Fit for Calibrated Models , 1991, Journal of Political Economy.

[45]  Reconsidering the Costs of Business Cycles with Incomplete Markets , 1994, NBER Macroeconomics Annual.

[46]  James Dolmas Risk Preferences and the Welfare Cost of Business Cycles , 1998 .

[47]  John Geweke,et al.  Posterior simulators in econometrics , 1995 .

[48]  Federal Reserve Board , 2005 .

[49]  Roger E. A. Farmer,et al.  Indeterminacy and sector-specific externalities , 1996 .

[50]  Ellen R. McGrattan,et al.  The macroeconomic effects of distortionary taxation , 1994 .

[51]  H. Uhlig,et al.  Can Habit Formation be Reconciled with Business Cycle Facts , 1995 .

[52]  Julio J. Rotemberg,et al.  Real-Business-Cycle Models and the Forecastable Movements in Output, Hours, and Consumption , 1996 .

[53]  P. Klein,et al.  Using the generalized Schur form to solve a multivariate linear rational expectations model q , 1997 .

[54]  Timothy Cogley,et al.  Effects of the Hodrick-Prescott filter on trend and difference stationary time series Implications for business cycle research , 1995 .

[55]  Lawrence J. Christiano,et al.  Asset Pricing Lessons for Modeling Business Cycles , 1995 .

[56]  M. Eichenbaum,et al.  A Time Series Analysis of Representative Agent Models of Consumption Andleisure Choice Under Uncertainty , 1986 .

[57]  Lawrence J. Christiano,et al.  HABIT PERSISTENCE AND ASSET RETURNS IN AN EXCHANGE ECONOMY , 1997, Macroeconomic Dynamics.