Characterizations of scoring methods for preference aggregation

The paper surveys more than forty characterizations of scoring methods for preference aggregation and contains one new result. A general scoring operator is {\it self-consistent} if alternative $i$ is assigned a greater score than $j$ whenever $i$ gets no worse (better) results of comparisons and its `opponents' are assigned respectively greater (no smaller) scores than those of $j$. We prove that self-consistency is satisfied if and only if the application of a scoring operator reduces to the solution of a homogeneous system of algebraic equations with a monotone function on the left-hand side.

[1]  Anna Borisovna Khmelnitskaya Social Choice Problems with Different Scales of Individual Welfares Measurement for Different Subgroups of Individuals , 1996 .

[2]  D. Bouyssou,et al.  Ranking methods for valued preference relations: A characterization of a method based on leaving and entering flows , 1992 .

[3]  Amartya Sen,et al.  On Weights and Measures: Informational Constraints in Social Welfare Analysis , 1977 .

[4]  Donald G. Saari,et al.  The Borda dictionary , 1990 .

[5]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  On Harsanyi's utilitarian cardinal welfare theorem , 1984 .

[6]  P. Fishburn A comparative analysis of group decision methods , 1971 .

[7]  L. Seiford,et al.  On the Borda-Kendall Consensus Method for Priority Ranking Problems , 1982 .

[8]  Boaz Golany,et al.  Deriving weights from pairwise comparison matrices: The additive case , 1990 .

[9]  Ernest Rubin,et al.  Questions and Answers: Adjusting Baseball Standings for Strength of Teams Played , 1956 .

[10]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  SUMMATION SOCIAL CHOICE FUNCTIONS , 1973 .

[11]  L. Gevers,et al.  Leximin and utilitarian rules: A joint characterization , 1978 .

[12]  Ariel Rubinstein,et al.  A further characterization of Borda ranking method , 1981 .

[13]  Yongsheng Xu,et al.  Independent necessary and sufficient conditions for approval voting , 1991 .

[14]  H. Moulin Axioms of Cooperative Decision Making , 1988 .

[15]  Peter J. Coughlin A direct characterization of Black's first borda count , 1979 .

[16]  J. Marcus Fleming Cardinal Welfare and Individualistic Ethics: A Comment , 1957, Journal of Political Economy.

[17]  Dudley J. Cowden,et al.  A Method of Evaluating Contestants , 1975 .

[18]  K. Fine,et al.  Social Choice and Individual Rankings II , 1974 .

[19]  Kevin Roberts,et al.  Interpersonal Comparability and Social Choice Theory , 1980 .

[20]  D. Bouyssou Ranking methods based on valued preference relations: A characterization of the net flow method , 1992 .

[21]  P. Pattanaik Risk, Impersonality, and the Social Welfare Function , 1968, Journal of Political Economy.

[22]  C. d'Aspremont,et al.  Equity and the Informational Basis of Collective Choice , 1977 .

[23]  Peter Gärdenfors Positionalist voting functions , 1973 .

[24]  P. Chebotarev Aggregation of preferences by the generalized row sum method , 1994 .

[25]  Denis Bouyssou,et al.  A note on the sum of differences choice function for fuzzy preference relations , 1992 .

[26]  Christos H. Papadimitriou,et al.  Games against nature , 1983, 24th Annual Symposium on Foundations of Computer Science (sfcs 1983).

[27]  Roger B. Myerson,et al.  Utilitarianism, Egalitarianism, and the Timing Effect in Social Choice Problems , 1981 .

[28]  John C. Harsanyi,et al.  Nonlinear social welfare functions , 1975 .

[29]  E. Zermelo Die Berechnung der Turnier-Ergebnisse als ein Maximumproblem der Wahrscheinlichkeitsrechnung , 1929 .

[30]  D. J Hartfiel,et al.  A characterization result for the plurality rule , 1978 .

[31]  Pavel Yu. Chebotarev,et al.  Preference fusion when the number of alternatives exceeds two: indirect scoring procedures , 1999, ArXiv.

[32]  A. Rubinstein Ranking the Participants in a Tournament , 1980 .

[33]  Roger B. Myerson,et al.  Axiomatic derivation of scoring rules without the ordering assumption , 1993 .

[34]  Thierry Marchant,et al.  Cardinality and the borda score , 1998, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[35]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Interprofile Conditions And Impossibility , 1987 .

[36]  Bengt Hansson,et al.  A proof technique for social choice with variable electorate , 1976 .

[37]  Dominique Henriet,et al.  The Copeland choice function an axiomatic characterization , 1985 .

[38]  C. John,et al.  Utilitarianism and beyond: Morality and the theory of rational behaviour , 1982 .

[39]  Eric Maskin,et al.  A Theorem on Utilitarianism , 1978 .

[40]  R. Keeney A Group Preference Axiomatization with Cardinal Utility , 1976 .

[41]  Jean-François Laslier,et al.  Tournament Solutions And Majority Voting , 1997 .

[42]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Axioms for approval voting: Direct proof , 1978 .

[43]  Salvador Barberà,et al.  Majority and Positional Voting in a Probabilistic Framework , 1979 .

[44]  G. Debreu Topological Methods in Cardinal Utility Theory , 1959 .

[45]  H. Young Social Choice Scoring Functions , 1975 .

[46]  蔡森昌 饒斯對功效主義(Utilitarianism)的批評 , 1994 .

[47]  J. Barzilai,et al.  Consistent weights for judgements matrices of the relative importance of alternatives , 1987 .

[48]  J. Marschak Rational Behavior, Uncertain Prospects, and Measurable Utility (1950) , 1950 .

[49]  A. Sen,et al.  Social Choice Theory: A Re-Examination , 1977 .

[50]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Preferences, Summation, and Social Welfare Functions , 1969 .

[51]  D. G. Saari,et al.  Consistency of decision processes , 1990 .

[52]  T. Marchant Valued relations aggregation with the borda method , 1996 .

[53]  H. P. Young,et al.  An axiomatization of Borda's rule , 1974 .

[54]  J. H. Smith AGGREGATION OF PREFERENCES WITH VARIABLE ELECTORATE , 1973 .

[55]  H. Daniels Round-robin tournament scores , 1969 .

[56]  Jill Van Newenhizen The Borda method is most likely to respect the Condorcet principle , 1992 .

[57]  Bernard Debord,et al.  An axiomatic characterization of Borda's k-choice function , 1992 .

[58]  P. Chebotarev,et al.  Constructing an Objective Function for Aggregating Incomplete Preferences , 1997 .

[59]  H. Gulliksen A least squares solution for paired comparisons with incomplete data , 1956 .

[60]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Should social choice be based on binary comparisons , 1971 .

[61]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Borda's rule, positional voting, and Condorcet's simple majority principle , 1976 .

[62]  G. Debreu Mathematical Economics: Representation of a preference ordering by a numerical function , 1983 .

[63]  E. Rowland Theory of Games and Economic Behavior , 1946, Nature.

[64]  Leo Katz,et al.  A new status index derived from sociometric analysis , 1953 .

[65]  L. A. Goodman,et al.  Social Welfare Functions Based on Individual Rankings , 1952, American Journal of Sociology.

[66]  Shmuel Nitzan,et al.  The Borda Rule and Pareto Stability: A Comment , 1979 .

[67]  J. Harsanyi Cardinal Welfare, Individualistic Ethics, and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility , 1955 .

[68]  H. Young,et al.  A Consistent Extension of Condorcet’s Election Principle , 1978 .

[69]  M. Fleming,et al.  A Cardinal Concept of Welfare , 1952 .

[70]  John R. Chamberlin,et al.  Representative Deliberations and Representative Decisions: Proportional Representation and the Borda Rule , 1983, American Political Science Review.

[71]  N. Schofield The Geometry of Voting , 1983 .