Social and economic challenges in the development of complex farming systems

The fundamental challenge in developing a new farming system is to have it adopted and maintained by farmers. The difficulty of achieving widespread adoption is increased if the new farming system is complex and/or radically different to current farming practice. This paper is a review of these issues with a focus on farming systems based on mimicry of natural ecosystems. It is proposed that there are four conditions which are necessary for an individual farmer to adopt an innovative farming-system: awareness of the innovation, perception that it is feasible to trial the innovation, perception that the innovation is worth trialing, and perception that the innovation promotes the farmer's objectives. Challenges involved in meeting each of these conditions are discussed. It is concluded that the most important challenges in developed countries are: (a) developing a farming system that is in fact more profitable than current practice; (b) assessing whether a system is in fact more profitable than current practice; and (c) overcoming the problem of deep uncertainty about the technology. In developing countries one must add the additional challenges of (d) high interest rates/high discount rates; and (e) insecure or inequitable land tenure.

[1]  R. Myers Econometric testing for risk averse behaviour in agriculture , 1989 .

[2]  E. Rogers,et al.  Diffusion of innovations , 1964, Encyclopedia of Sport Management.

[3]  D. A. King,et al.  Adoption of Soil Conservation Measures in Manilla Shire, New South Wales , 1990 .

[4]  E. Rogers,et al.  Diffusion of Innovations , 1964 .

[5]  J. Antle Econometric Estimation of Producers' Risk Attitudes , 1987 .

[6]  J. Cary,et al.  PERCEIVED PROFITABILITY AND FARMERS‘ CONSERVATION BEHAVIOUR , 1997 .

[7]  D. Pannell,et al.  The Adoption Of Lupins In Western Australia: Did Extension Make A Difference? , 1995 .

[8]  Sam Fujisaka,et al.  Learning from six reasons why farmers do not adopt innovations intended to improve sustainability of upland agriculture , 1994 .

[9]  Philip G. Pardey,et al.  DISTANCE TO INFORMATION SOURCE AND THE TIME LAG TO EARLY ADOPTION OF TRACE ELEMENT FERTILISERS , 1982 .

[10]  J. Mortensen,et al.  David W. Pearce and R. Kerry Turner, Economics of Natural Resources and the Environment. London: Harvester Wheatsheaf, 1990; 378 s. $ 22.95. , 1991 .

[11]  Gershon Feder,et al.  The adoption of agricultural innovations: A review , 1993 .

[12]  D. Pannell Economic aspects of legume management and legume research in dryland farming systems of southern Australia , 1995 .

[13]  A. Main How much biodiversity is enough? , 1999, Agroforestry Systems.

[14]  W. Jackson,et al.  Meeting the Expectations of the Land: Essays in Sustainable Agriculture and Stewardship , 1985 .

[15]  Gershon Feder,et al.  Land Ownership Security and Farm Investment in Thailand , 1987 .

[16]  David Zilberman,et al.  Adoption of Agricultural Innovations in Developing Countries: A Survey , 1985, Economic Development and Cultural Change.

[17]  G. E. Bond,et al.  RISK ATTITUDES AMONGST AUSTRALIAN FARMERS , 1980 .

[18]  P. Bardsley,et al.  An Approach To The Econometric Estimation Of Attitudes To Risk In Agriculture , 1987 .

[19]  H. P. Binswanger Attitudes toward risk: Experimental measurement in rural india , 1980 .

[20]  Can Producers Place Valid and Reliable Valuations on Wool Price-Risk Information? , 1995 .