Anonymity in Giving in a Natural Context : A Field Experiment in 30 Churches

Abstract The role of anonymity in giving is examined in a field experiment performed in 30 Dutch churches. For a period of 29 weeks, the means by which offerings are gathered is determined by chance, prescribing for each offering the use of either ‘closed’ collection bags or open collection baskets. When using baskets, attendees can see the contribution made by their direct neighbors as well as the total amount already gathered. Contributions to offerings with an external cause initially increase by 10% when baskets are used, but this effect peters out over time. No effect is found for offerings with an internal cause. This result can be explained by the presence of social incentives, but is also in line with recent studies showing that asymmetric information about the quality of the charity leads to increased contributions.

[1]  Robert Kurzban,et al.  Conditional cooperation and group dynamics: Experimental evidence from a sequential public goods game , 2003 .

[2]  Catherine C. Eckel,et al.  Rebates Versus Matching: Does How We Subsidize Charitable Contributions Matter? , 2003 .

[3]  E. Fehr,et al.  Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity , 2000, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[4]  Robert J. Stonebraker Optimal Church Size: The Bigger the Better? , 1993 .

[5]  David Lucking-Reiley,et al.  The Effects of Seed Money and Refunds on Charitable Giving: Experimental Evidence from a University Capital Campaign , 2002, Journal of Political Economy.

[6]  M. Haan,et al.  Free riding and the provision of candy bars , 2002 .

[7]  Charles R. Plott,et al.  Public goods provision in an experimental environment , 1985 .

[8]  V. Smith,et al.  Social distance and other-regarding behavior in dictator games , 2000 .

[9]  J. Andreoni,et al.  Public goods experiments without confidentiality: a glimpse into fund-raising , 2004 .

[10]  Paul M. Brown,et al.  What Makes an Allocation Fair? Some Experimental Evidence , 2002, Games Econ. Behav..

[11]  C. Noussair,et al.  Monetary and Non-Monetary Punishment in the Voluntary Contributions Mechanism , 2003 .

[12]  Charles E. Zech,et al.  Economic and attitudinal factors in catholic and protestant religious giving , 1994 .

[13]  Lise Vesterlund,et al.  The informational value of sequential fundraising , 2003 .

[14]  Jody W. Lipford,et al.  Group size and the free-rider hypothesis: An examination of new evidence from churches , 1995 .

[15]  Herbert Gintis,et al.  Prosocial Emotions , 2003 .

[16]  E. Fehr,et al.  Collective action as a social exchange , 1999 .

[17]  Kjetil Telle,et al.  The impact of social approval and framing on cooperation in public good situations , 2004 .

[18]  Charles E. Zech,et al.  Group size and the free-rider hypothesis: A re-examination of old evidence from churches: Comment , 1996 .

[19]  Dennis H. Sullivan Simultaneous Determination of Church Contributions and Church Attendance , 1985 .

[20]  L. Iannaccone,et al.  Introduction to the Economics of Religion , 1998 .

[21]  V. Smith,et al.  Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games: Reply , 1999 .

[22]  Gary E. Bolton,et al.  ERC: A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity, and Competition , 2000 .

[23]  E. Fehr A Theory of Fairness, Competition and Cooperation , 1998 .

[24]  William T. Harbaugh The Prestige Motive for Making Charitable Transfers , 1998 .

[25]  J. Sonnemans,et al.  UvA-DARE ( Digital Academic Repository ) Social ties in a public good experiment , 1997 .

[26]  Gordon Tullock On “Group size and the free-rider hypothesis: Another hypothesis.” by Jody W. Lipford: Comment , 1996 .

[27]  Terence C. Burnham,et al.  Engineering altruism: a theoretical and experimental investigation of anonymity and gift giving , 2003 .

[28]  William T. Harbaugh What do donations buy?: A model of philanthropy based on prestige and warm glow , 1998 .