Who ought to be elected and who is actually elected? An empirical investigation of 92 elections under three procedures

Abstract Three voting procedures—Borda's Count (BR), Plurality Voting (PV), and the Single Transferable Vote (STV)—are compared with one another in relation to the outcomes of 92 real elections conducted in Britain by various trade unions, professional associations, and non-profit organizations. Given the social preference ordering (SPO) among the n competing candidates, of whom m candidates must be elected ( n > m ⩾ 1), each of these procedures is evaluated by means of two new indices that measure the discrepancy between the m candidates elected and the prescription of the majoritarian principle. For two of these procedures (PV and STV), we also investigate the relative frequency with which they display the recently discovered Discontinuity Paradox, namely, cases where a candidate who would be elected when m candidates must be elected would not also be elected, ceteris paribus , if m + 1 candidates were to be elected. Our analysis supports the following three conclusions: 1. (i) When m = 1, STV (or rather its Alternative Vote variant) conforms better with the SPO than do the other two procedures, particularly PV. 2. (ii) When m > 1, BR conforms with the SPO significantly better than do the other two procedures, particularly STV. 3. (iii) PV is likely to display the Discontinuity Paradox more often than STV. Since BR is not susceptible to the Discontinuity Paradox, we conclude that, in terms of avoiding this paradox and conforming with the SPO, BR performs better than both PV and STV.

[1]  A note on some generalizations of the paradox of cyclical majorities , 1972 .

[2]  Leigh Tesfatsion,et al.  Fair division with uncertain needs and tastes , 1985 .

[3]  Robert M. May,et al.  Some mathematical remarks on the paradox of voting , 1971 .

[4]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Majority efficiencies for simple voting procedures: Summary and interpretation , 1982 .

[5]  Amnon Rapoport,et al.  Proportional representation: An empirical evaluation of single-stage, non-ranked voting procedures , 1988 .

[6]  John C. Blydenburgh,et al.  The Closed Rule and the Paradox of Voting , 1971, The Journal of Politics.

[7]  A. Rapoport,et al.  An Empirical Evaluation of Six Voting Procedures: Do They Really Make Any Difference? , 1993, British Journal of Political Science.

[8]  Shmuel Nitzan,et al.  The vulnerability of point-voting schemes to preference variation and strategic manipulation , 1985 .

[9]  David C. Fisher,et al.  Optimal strategies for a generalized “scissors, paper, and stone” game , 1992 .

[10]  Amnon Rapoport,et al.  The condorcet-efficiency of sophisticated voting under the plurality and approval procedures , 1990 .

[11]  P. Slater Inconsistencies in a schedule of paired comparisons , 1961 .

[12]  L. A. Goodman,et al.  Social Choice and Individual Values , 1951 .

[13]  H. Moulin Choosing from a tournament , 1986 .

[14]  Samuel Merrill,et al.  A statistical model for Condorcet efficiency based on simulation under spatial model assumptions , 1985 .

[15]  Thomas R. Palfrey,et al.  Laboratory research in political economy , 1991 .

[16]  Douglas W. Mitchell,et al.  Frequency of paradox in a common n-winner voting scheme , 1992 .

[17]  Amnon Rapoport,et al.  Tacit co-operation in three-alternative non-cooperative voting games: A new model of sophisticated behaviour under the plurality procedure , 1988 .

[18]  M. Breton,et al.  The Bipartisan Set of a Tournament Game , 1993 .

[19]  P. Fishburn Condorcet Social Choice Functions , 1977 .

[20]  P.-C.-F. Daunou,et al.  Mémoire sur les élections au scrutin , 1803 .

[21]  C. Plott,et al.  The Probability of a Cyclical Majority , 1970 .

[22]  R. Niemi,et al.  A mathematical solution for the probability of the paradox of voting. , 1968, Behavioral science.

[23]  Nicholas R. Miller A New Solution Set for Tournaments and Majority Voting: Further Graph- Theoretical Approaches to the Theory of Voting , 1980 .

[24]  David Klahr,et al.  A Computer Simulation of the Paradox of Voting , 1966, American Political Science Review.

[25]  Jill Van Newenhizen The Borda method is most likely to respect the Condorcet principle , 1992 .

[26]  Scott L. Feld,et al.  Collectivities as Actors , 1990 .

[27]  Bhaskar Dutta Covering sets and a new condorcet choice correspondence , 1988 .

[28]  Dale T. Hoffman,et al.  Relative Efficiency of Voting Systems , 1983 .

[29]  Peter C. Fishburn Single‐peaked preferences and probabilities of cyclical majorities , 1974 .

[30]  Scott L. Feld,et al.  Who's Afraid of the Big Bad Cycle? Evidence from 36 Elections , 1992 .

[31]  Richard G. Niemi,et al.  Sophisticated voting under the plurality procedure: A test of a new definition , 1985 .

[32]  Robert F. Bordley,et al.  A Pragmatic Method for Evaluating Election Schemes through Simulation , 1983, American Political Science Review.

[33]  M. Kamien,et al.  The paradox of voting: probability calculations. , 1968, Behavioral science.

[34]  T. Schwartz Rationality and the Myth of the Maximum , 1972 .

[35]  Clyde H. Coombs,et al.  Social Choice Observed: Five Presidential Elections of the American Psychological Association , 1984, The Journal of Politics.

[36]  D. Felsenthal Proportional representation under three voting procedures: An Israeli study , 1992 .

[37]  John R. Wright,et al.  Voting cycles and the structure of individual preferences , 1987 .

[38]  S. Merrill A Comparison of Efficiency of Multicandidate Electoral Systems , 1984 .

[39]  Dan S. Felsenthal,et al.  After two centuries, should condorcet's voting procedure be implemented? , 1992 .

[40]  R. Niemi The occurrence of the paradox of voting in University elections , 1970 .

[41]  J. Banks Sophisticated voting outcomes and agenda control , 1984 .

[42]  D. Felsenthal,et al.  Normative properties of four single-stage multi-winner electoral procedures , 1992 .

[43]  Thomas Schwartz Cyclic tournaments and cooperative majority voting: A solution , 1990 .

[44]  Richard G. Niemi,et al.  Probability models of collective decision making , 1972 .