Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of Interaction Effects

Companies spend millions of dollars on advertising to boost a brand's image and simultaneously spend millions of dollars on promotion that many believe calls attention to price and erodes brand equity. We believe this paradoxical situation exists because both advertising and promotion are necessary to compete effectively in dynamic markets. Consequently, brand managers need to account for interactions between marketing activities and interactions among competing brands. By recognizing interaction effects between activities, managers can consider interactivity trade-offs in planning the marketing-mix strategies. On the other hand, by recognizing interactions with competitors, managers can incorporate strategic foresight in their planning, which requires them to look forward and reason backward in making optimal decisions. Looking forward means that each brand manager anticipates how other competing brands are likely to make future decisions, and then by reasoning backward deduces one's own optimal decisions in response to the best decisions to be made by all other brands. The joint consideration of interaction effects and strategic foresight in planning marketing-mix strategies is a challenging and unsolved marketing problem, which motivates this paper. This paper investigates the problem of planning marketing mix in dynamic competitive markets. We extend the Lanchester model by incorporating interaction effects, constructing the marketing-mix algorithm that yields marketing-mix plans with strategic foresight, and developing the continuous-discrete estimation method to calibrate dynamic models of oligopoly using market data. Both the marketing-mix algorithm and the estimation method are general, so they can be applied to any other alternative model specifications for dynamic oligopoly markets. Thus, this dual methodology augments the decision-making toolkit of managers, empowering them to tackle realistic marketing problems in dynamic oligopoly markets. We illustrate the application of this dual methodology by studying the dynamic Lanchester competition across five brands in the detergents market, where each brand uses advertising and promotion to influence its own market share and the shares of competing brands. Empirically, we find that advertising and promotion not only affect the brand shares own and competitors' but also exert interaction effects, i.e., each activity amplifies or attenuates the effectiveness of the other activity. Normatively, we find that large brands underadvertise and overspend on promotion, while small brands underadvertise and underpromote. Finally, comparative statics reveal managerial insights into how a specific brand should respond optimally to the changes in a competing brand's situation; more generally, we find evidence that competitive responsiveness is asymmetric.

[1]  M. L. Vidale,et al.  An Operations-Research Study of Sales Response to Advertising , 1957 .

[2]  F. Bass A Simultaneous Equation Regression Study of Advertising and Sales of Cigarettes , 1969 .

[3]  Michael R. Osborne,et al.  Numerical solution of boundary value problems for ordinary differential equations , 1995, Classics in applied mathematics.

[4]  Leonard J. Parsons,et al.  An Econometric Analysis of Advertising, Retail Availability, and Sales of a New Brand , 1974 .

[5]  J. Durbin,et al.  Techniques for Testing the Constancy of Regression Relationships Over Time , 1975 .

[6]  Michael L. Ray,et al.  Advertising–selling interactions: An attribution theory experiment. , 1977 .

[7]  S. Sethi Dynamic Optimal Control Models in Advertising: A Survey , 1977 .

[8]  John D. C. Little,et al.  Feature Article - Aggregate Advertising Models: The State of the Art , 1979, Oper. Res..

[9]  Kenneth R. Deal Optimizing Advertising Expenditures in a Dynamic Duopoly , 1979, Oper. Res..

[10]  J. Simon The shape of the advertising response function , 1980 .

[11]  P. M. E. Altham,et al.  Improving the Precision of Estimation by Fitting a Model , 1984 .

[12]  Gerald L. Thompson,et al.  Optimal Pricing and Advertising Policies for New Product Oligopoly Models , 1984 .

[13]  Vijay Mahajan,et al.  Advertising Pulsing Policies for Generating Awareness for New Products , 1986 .

[14]  Ram C. Rao,et al.  Estimating Continuous Time Advertising-Sales Models , 1986 .

[15]  F. Lewis Optimal Estimation: With an Introduction to Stochastic Control Theory , 1986 .

[16]  Dominique M. Hanssens,et al.  Modeling Marketing Interactions with Application to Salesforce Effectiveness , 1987 .

[17]  Clifford M. Hurvich,et al.  Regression and time series model selection in small samples , 1989 .

[18]  Robert C. Blattberg,et al.  Sales Promotion: Concepts, Methods, and Strategies , 1990 .

[19]  Gary M. Erickson Dynamic Models of Advertising Competition: Open- and Closed-Loop Extensions , 1991 .

[20]  James D. Hess,et al.  A Theory of Channel Price Promotions , 1991 .

[21]  Pradeep K. Chintagunta,et al.  Marketing investment decisions in a dynamic duopoly: A model and empirical analysis , 1994 .

[22]  S. Neslin,et al.  The effects of retailer and consumer response on optimal manufacturer advertising and trade promotion strategies , 1995 .

[23]  G. Erickson Differential game models of advertising competition , 1995 .

[24]  L. Gary,et al.  ABELL F. Dereck, Defining The Business. The Starting Point of Strategic Planning . USA, Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, 1980. , 1996 .

[25]  R. Staelin,et al.  Vertical Strategic Interaction: Implications for Channel Pricing Strategy , 1997 .

[26]  Donald R. Lehmann,et al.  The Long-Term Impact of Promotion and Advertising on Consumer Brand Choice , 1997 .

[27]  D. B. Montgomery,et al.  Rational Strategic Reasoning: An Unnatural Act? , 1998 .

[28]  Gila E. Fruchter,et al.  Dynamic promotional budgeting and media allocation , 1998, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[29]  Prasad A. Naik,et al.  Planning Media Schedules in the Presence of Dynamic Advertising Quality , 1998 .

[30]  Carl F. Mela,et al.  The Dynamic Effect of Discounting on Sales: Empirical Analysis and Normative Pricing Implications , 1999 .

[31]  David R. Anderson,et al.  Model Selection and Inference: A Practical Information-Theoretic Approach , 2001 .

[32]  Harald J. van Heerde,et al.  Semiparametric Analysis to Estimate the Deal Effect Curve , 2001 .

[33]  Dick R. Wittink,et al.  The Estimation of Pre- and Postpromotion Dips with Store-Level Scanner Data , 2000 .

[34]  J. M. Villas-Boas,et al.  Endogeneity in Brand Choice Models , 1999 .

[35]  Carl F. Mela,et al.  Managing Advertising and Promotion for Long-Run Profitability , 1999 .

[36]  D. G. Morrison,et al.  A Decision Support System for Planning Manufacturers' Sales Promotion Calendars , 1999 .

[37]  Prasad A. Naik,et al.  Controlling Measurement Errors in Models of Advertising Competition , 2000 .

[38]  Ngo Van Long,et al.  Differential Games in Economics and Management Science: List of tables , 2000 .

[39]  E. Dockner,et al.  Differential Games in Economics and Management Science , 2001 .

[40]  Fred M. Feinberg,et al.  On Continuous-Time Optimal Advertising Under S-Shaped Response , 2001, Manag. Sci..

[41]  Prasad A. Naik,et al.  Single‐index model selections , 2001 .

[42]  Dick R. Wittink,et al.  Explaining competitive reaction effects , 2001 .

[43]  Prasad A. Naik,et al.  Understanding the Impact of Synergy in Multimedia Communications , 2003 .

[44]  Prasad A. Naik,et al.  Residual information criterion for single-index model selections , 2004 .

[45]  Dick R. Wittink,et al.  Decomposing the Sales Promotion Bump with Store Data , 2004 .

[46]  Sridhar Moorthy,et al.  A General Theory of Pass-Through in Channels with Category Management and Retail Competition , 2005 .

[47]  Robert H. Shumway,et al.  Time Series Analysis and Its Applications (Springer Texts in Statistics) , 2005 .

[48]  David Besanko,et al.  Own-Brand and Cross-Brand Retail Pass-Through , 2005 .

[49]  竹安 数博,et al.  Time series analysis and its applications , 2007 .