Dynamic Game Results of the Acquisition of New Technology

Open and closed-loop Nash strategies are derived and analyzed for a differential game in which two competing firms choose prices and productive capacity where new technology reduces a firm's unit operating cost. Using an open-loop strategy, a firm makes an irreversible commitment to a future course of action. For example, a contract with a labor union may force a firm to commit to maintaining its entire workforce regardless of its competitor's future realized behavior. In contrast, using a closed-loop strategy, a firm's decisions evolve over time, continuously responding to the competitor's behavior. The dynamic Nash strategies obtained for the closed-loop model exhibit a more restricted acquisition of new technology and a greater reduction of existing capacity relative to the open-loop solutions. In addition, the dynamic Nash price to be charged for output is higher in the closed as opposed to open-loop competitive environment. Numerical solutions are presented to demonstrate that if both firms apply the closed-loop approach, each will earn higher profits than if one or both firms choose an open-loop strategy.

[1]  George Leitmann,et al.  Profit maximization through advertising: A nonzero sum differential game approach , 1978 .

[2]  Hirohide Hinomoto,et al.  Capacity Expansion with Facilities Under Technological Improvement , 1965 .

[3]  Kenneth R. Deal Optimizing Advertising Expenditures in a Dynamic Duopoly , 1979, Oper. Res..

[4]  G. Olsder,et al.  On the linear-quadratic, closed-loop, no-memory Nash game , 1984 .

[5]  Stephen R. Rosenthal,et al.  Progress toward the “factory of the future” , 1984 .

[6]  Y. Ho,et al.  Nonzero-sum differential games , 1969 .

[7]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  Dynamic Models of Oligopoly , 1986 .

[8]  Cheryl Gaimon,et al.  The Acquisition of Automation Subject to Diminishing Returns , 1985 .

[9]  D. Gerwin,et al.  Do's and Dont's of Computerized Manufacturing , 1982 .

[10]  Morton I. Kamien,et al.  SOME ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF ANTICIPATING TECHNICAL ADVANCE , 1972 .

[11]  G. Feichtinger A Differential Games Solution to a Model of Competition Between a Thief and the Police , 1983 .

[12]  J. G. Klincewicz,et al.  Optimal timing decisions for the introduction of new technologies , 1985 .

[13]  Jr. Mikell P. Groover Automation, production systems, and computer-aided manufacturing , 1980 .

[14]  George K. Hutchinson,et al.  The economic value of flexible automation , 1982 .

[15]  G. Thompson,et al.  Optimal control theory : applications to management science , 1984 .

[16]  Stanley S. Reynolds,et al.  Capacity Investment, Preemption and Commitment in an Infinite Horizon Model , 1987 .

[17]  Gerald L. Thompson,et al.  Oligopoly Models for Optimal Advertising When Production Costs Obey a Learning Curve , 1983 .

[18]  Jennifer F. Reinganum On the diffusion of new technology: A game theoretic approach , 1981 .

[19]  Steffen Jørgensen,et al.  Cooperative and Non-Cooperative Differential Game Solutions to an Investment and Pricing Problem , 1984 .

[20]  Cheryl Gaimon,et al.  The Optimal Acquisition of Automation to Enhance the Productivity of Labor , 1985 .

[21]  Eddie Anderson,et al.  Operations Management—Strategy and Analysis , 1987 .

[22]  Gustav Feichtinger,et al.  The Nash solution of a maintenance-production differential game , 1982 .

[23]  J. Ettlie,et al.  Organization Strategy and Structural Differences for Radical Versus Incremental Innovation , 1984 .

[24]  Jennifer F. Reinganum A class of differential games for which the closed-loop and open-loop Nash equilibria coincide , 1982 .

[25]  Suresh P. Sethi,et al.  A Bilinear-Quadratic Differential Game in Advertising. , 1978 .

[26]  M. C. Burstein,et al.  Economic evaluation for the optimal introduction of flexible manufacturing technology under rivalry , 1985 .