Looking ahead: Subjective time perception and individual discounting

We disentangle hyperbolic discounting from subjective time perception using experimental data from incentive-compatible tests to measure time preferences, and a set of experimental tasks to measure time perception. Two behavioral parameters are related to two factors affecting how we look ahead to future events. The first is some component of time preferences reflecting hyperbolic discounting. The second factor is that non-constant discounting may also be a reflection of subjective time perception: if people’s perception of time follows a near logarithmic process (as heat, sound, and light do) then estimates of individual discounting will be mis-measured and incorrectly suggest hyperbolic discounting even if discounting over subjective time is constant. We empirically estimate the two distinct behavioral parameters using data collected from 178 participants in a lab experiment. The results support the hypothesis that apparent non-constant discounting is largely a reflection of non-linear subjective time perception.

[1]  Stephen L. Cheung,et al.  Risk Preferences Are Not Time Preferences: On the Elicitation of Time Preference under Conditions of Risk: Comment , 2015 .

[2]  S. S. Stevens On the psychophysical law. , 1957, Psychological review.

[3]  J. Pender Discount rates and credit markets" Theory and evidence from rural india , 1996 .

[4]  Shanefrederick,et al.  Time Discounting and Time Preference : A Critical Review , 2022 .

[5]  Aldo Rustichini,et al.  Cognitive skills affect economic preferences, strategic behavior, and job attachment , 2009, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[6]  M. Coller,et al.  Eliciting Individual Discount Rates , 1999 .

[7]  S. Cheung Eliciting utility curvature in time preference , 2019, Experimental Economics.

[8]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Decision making over time and under uncertainty: a common approach , 1991 .

[9]  Richard Wahlund,et al.  Mental discounting and financial strategies , 1996 .

[10]  Judy Czylok A SENSE OF TOUCH , 1979, Nursing standard (Royal College of Nursing (Great Britain) : 1987).

[11]  Daniel Read,et al.  Can intertemporal choice experiments elicit time preferences for consumption? , 2007 .

[12]  Selin A. Malkoc,et al.  Discounting Time and Time Discounting: Subjective Time Perception and Intertemporal Preferences , 2008 .

[13]  Gretchen B. Chapman,et al.  The magnitude effect: Temporal discount rates and restaurant tips , 1998 .

[14]  R. Baumeister,et al.  High self-control predicts good adjustment, less pathology, better grades, and interpersonal success. , 2004, Journal of personality.

[15]  David Laibson,et al.  Individual laboratory-measured discount rates predict field behavior , 2008, Journal of risk and uncertainty.

[16]  Peter H. M. P. Roelofsma,et al.  Modelling intertemporal choices: An anomaly approach. , 1996 .

[17]  J. Quiggin,et al.  Bounded awareness and anomalies in intertemporal choice: Zooming in Google Earth as both metaphor and model , 2017, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty.

[18]  Daniel Read,et al.  Discounting by Intervals: A Generalized Model of Intertemporal Choice , 2006, Manag. Sci..

[19]  Julian C. Jamison,et al.  Characterizing the Amount and Speed of Discounting Procedures , 2011, Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis.

[20]  Y. Trope,et al.  Construal-level theory of psychological distance. , 2010, Psychological review.

[21]  G. Silvestri,et al.  Estimating the Effect of Individual Time Preferences on the Use of Disease Screening , 2010 .

[22]  Viewing the Future Through a Warped Lens: Why Uncertainty Generates Hyperbolic Discounting , 2010 .

[23]  G. Ainslie Specious reward: a behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulse control. , 1975, Psychological bulletin.

[24]  P. Samuelson,et al.  Foundations of Economic Analysis. , 1948 .

[25]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review , 2002 .

[26]  Charles A. Holt,et al.  Risk Aversion and Incentive Effects , 2002 .

[27]  Glenn W. Harrison,et al.  Latent process heterogeneity in discounting behavior , 2012 .

[28]  Peter P. Wakker,et al.  Non-hyperbolic time inconsistency , 2009, Games Econ. Behav..

[29]  Stanislas Dehaene,et al.  The neural basis of the Weber–Fechner law: a logarithmic mental number line , 2003, Trends in Cognitive Sciences.

[30]  J. Hornik Subjective vs. Objective Time Measures: A Note on the Perception of Time in Consumer Behavior , 1984 .

[31]  Luis C. Corchón,et al.  Addiction and Cue-Triggered Decision Processes. , 2004, The American economic review.

[32]  Mohammed Abdellaoui,et al.  Is There One Unifying Concept of Utility?An Experimental Comparison of Utility Under Risk and Utility Over Time , 2013, Manag. Sci..

[33]  Susan K. Laury,et al.  Avoiding the curves: Direct elicitation of time preferences , 2011 .

[34]  S. Chaiken,et al.  Dual-process theories in social psychology , 1999 .

[35]  A. Tversky,et al.  The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. , 1981, Science.

[36]  B. Shiferaw,et al.  Poverty, market imperfections and time preferences: of relevance for environmental policy? , 1998, Environment and Development Economics.

[37]  Jane E. J. Ebert,et al.  The Fragility of Time: Time-Insensitivity and Valuation of the Near and Far Future , 2007, Manag. Sci..

[38]  Ola Andersson,et al.  Risk Aversion Relates to Cognitive Ability: Fact or Fiction? , 2013 .

[39]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Anomalies in Intertemporal Choice: Evidence and an Interpretation , 1992 .

[40]  H. Bleichrodt,et al.  Discounting health and money: New evidence using a more robust method , 2018, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty.

[41]  D A Redelmeier,et al.  Time Preference in Medical Decision Making and Cost - Effectiveness Analysis , 1993, Medical decision making : an international journal of the Society for Medical Decision Making.

[42]  K. Kirby,et al.  Modeling Myopic Decisions: Evidence for Hyperbolic Delay-Discounting within Subjects and Amounts , 1995 .

[43]  A. Rapoport,et al.  Discount rates inferred from decisions: an experimental study , 1987 .

[44]  Andrew Caplin,et al.  Measuring Self-Control Problems , 2007 .

[45]  M. Munafo,et al.  Delayed reward discounting and addictive behavior: a meta-analysis , 2011, Psychopharmacology.

[46]  R. H. Strotz Myopia and Inconsistency in Dynamic Utility Maximization , 1955 .

[47]  M. Paulus,et al.  Decision making, impulsivity and time perception , 2008, Trends in Cognitive Sciences.

[48]  J Cairns,et al.  Constant and decreasing timing aversion for saving lives. , 1997, Social science & medicine.

[49]  R. Thaler,et al.  An Economic Theory of Self-Control , 1977, Journal of Political Economy.

[50]  A. Falk,et al.  Interpreting Time Horizon Effects in Inter-Temporal Choice , 2012, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[51]  W. Bradford,et al.  The Association Between Individual Time Preferences and Health Maintenance Habits , 2010, Medical decision making : an international journal of the Society for Medical Decision Making.

[52]  Morten I. Lau,et al.  Eliciting Risk and Time Preferences , 2008 .

[53]  Jerry A. Hausman,et al.  Individual Discount Rates and the Purchase and Utilization of Energy-Using Durables , 1979 .

[54]  U. Ben-Zion,et al.  Discount rates inferred from decisions: an experimental study , 1989 .

[55]  Philipp Lergetporer,et al.  How to measure time preferences in children: a comparison of two methods , 2015 .

[56]  R. Thaler Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency , 1981 .

[57]  J. Patton,et al.  Factor structure of the Barratt impulsiveness scale. , 1995, Journal of clinical psychology.

[58]  Taiki Takahashi Loss of self-control in intertemporal choice may be attributable to logarithmic time-perception. , 2013, Medical hypotheses.

[59]  Beryl Hesketh,et al.  Time Perspective in Career-Related Choices: Applications of Time-Discounting Principles , 2000 .

[60]  Ayse Öncüler,et al.  Heterogeneous risk and time preferences , 2016 .

[61]  W. Bickel,et al.  Heroin addicts have higher discount rates for delayed rewards than non-drug-using controls. , 1999, Journal of experimental psychology. General.

[62]  G. Ainslie Derivation of "Rational" Economic Behavior from Hyperbolic Discount Curves , 1991 .

[63]  J. Cairns,et al.  Valuing future benefits. , 1994, Health economics.

[64]  Werner Güth,et al.  On the Interaction of Risk and Time Preferences: An Experimental Study , 2001 .

[65]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Risk and time preferences: linking experimental and household survey data from Vietnam , 2010 .

[66]  Kan Takeuchi,et al.  Non-Parametric Test of Time Consistency: Present Bias and Future Bias , 2010, Games Econ. Behav..

[67]  L. Green,et al.  Temporal discounting and preference reversals in choice between delayed outcomes , 1994, Psychonomic bulletin & review.

[68]  Michael J. Moore,et al.  The Quantity-Adjusted Value of Life , 1988 .

[69]  P. Wakker,et al.  Measuring discounting without measuring utility , 2016 .

[70]  Kan Takeuchi Non-Parametric Test of Time Consistency: Present Bias and Future Bias , 2011 .

[71]  A. Tversky,et al.  Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases , 1974, Science.

[72]  G. Zauberman,et al.  Perception of anticipatory time in temporal discounting. , 2009 .

[73]  B. O'Shaughnessy The sense of touch , 1989 .

[74]  Michael J. Moore,et al.  Discounting environmental health risks: New evidence and policy implications , 1990 .

[75]  Charles Sprenger,et al.  Measuring time preferences: A comparison of experimental methods ☆ , 2015 .

[76]  Faruk Gul,et al.  Temptation and Self‐Control , 1999 .

[77]  Keith H. Coble,et al.  At the nexus of risk and time preferences: An experimental investigation , 2010 .

[78]  Yaacov Trope,et al.  Temporal construal. , 2003, Psychological review.

[79]  Dermot Gately,et al.  Individual Discount Rates and the Purchase and Utilization of Energy-Using Durables: Comment , 1980 .

[80]  Martin P. Paulus,et al.  Temporal horizons in decision making. , 2009 .

[81]  D. Kahneman Maps of Bounded Rationality: Psychology for Behavioral Economics , 2003 .

[82]  L. Rüschendorf,et al.  On the Perception of Time , 2009, Gerontology.

[83]  J. Andreoni,et al.  Risk Preferences Are Not Time Preferences , 2012 .

[84]  J Cairns,et al.  Estimating time preferences for health using discrete choice experiments. , 2001, Social science & medicine.

[85]  G. Harrison,et al.  Can Intertemporal Choice Experiments Elicit Time Preferences for Consumption? Yes , 2011 .

[86]  R. Pollak,et al.  SECOND-BEST NATIONAL SAVING AND GAME-EQUILIBRIUM GROWTH , 1980 .

[87]  A. Tenbrunsel,et al.  Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes , 2013 .

[88]  W. Bickel,et al.  Shortened time horizons and insensitivity to future consequences in heroin addicts. , 1998, Addiction.

[89]  W. Bickel,et al.  Heroin addicts have higher discount rates for delayed rewards than non-drug-using controls. , 1999 .

[90]  A. Rubinstein International Economic Review " Economics and Psychology " ? the Case of Hyperbolic Discounting * , 2003 .

[91]  P. Wakker,et al.  A Direct Method for Measuring Discounting and QALYs More Easily and Reliably , 2012, Medical decision making : an international journal of the Society for Medical Decision Making.

[92]  Adrian Bruhin,et al.  Viewing the future through a warped lens: Why uncertainty generates hyperbolic discounting , 2010 .

[93]  Eliciting Individual Discount Rates , 1999 .

[94]  W. Kip Viscusi,et al.  The heterogeneity of time–risk tradeoffs , 2000 .

[95]  G. Loewenstein Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior , 1996 .

[96]  Drazen Prelec,et al.  Decreasing Impatience: A Criterion for Non-Stationary Time Preference and 'Hyperbolic' Discounting , 2004 .

[97]  Morten I. Lau,et al.  Estimating Individual Discount Rates in Denmark: A Field Experiment , 2002 .

[98]  D. Read Is Time-Discounting Hyperbolic or Subadditive? , 2001 .

[99]  Jess Benhabib,et al.  Present-bias, quasi-hyperbolic discounting, and fixed costs , 2010, Games Econ. Behav..

[100]  David I. Laibson,et al.  Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting , 1997 .

[101]  J. T. Warner,et al.  The Personal Discount Rate: Evidence from Military Downsizing Programs , 2001 .

[102]  Guy Michaels,et al.  Resetting the Urban Network: 117–2012 , 2013 .

[103]  S. Cheung,et al.  Recent Developments in the Experimental Elicitation of Time Preference , 2016, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[104]  Miles S. Kimball,et al.  Preference Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Survey , 1995 .

[105]  G. Chapman,et al.  Time Preferences and Preventive Health Behavior , 1999, Medical decision making : an international journal of the Society for Medical Decision Making.

[106]  A. Falk,et al.  Are Risk Aversion and Impatience Related to Cognitive Ability? , 2007, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[107]  P. Dolan,et al.  Time preference, duration and health state valuations. , 1995, Health economics.

[108]  Taiki Takahashi,et al.  Psychophysics of time perception and intertemporal choice models , 2008 .

[109]  Matthias Sutter,et al.  Working Papers in Economics and Statistics Group polarization in the team dictator game reconsidered , 2007 .

[110]  Glenn W. Harrison,et al.  Discounting behavior: A reconsideration☆ , 2014 .

[111]  Garth Heutel,et al.  NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TIME PREFERENCES AND CONSUMER BEHAVIOR , 2014 .

[112]  Thomas Epper,et al.  Risk preferences are not time preferences: balancing on a budget line: comment , 2015 .

[113]  Werner Güth,et al.  On the Interaction of Risk and Time Preferences , 1999 .

[114]  Per-Olov Johansson,et al.  Quality of life and the WTP for an increased life expectancy at an advanced age , 1997 .

[115]  G. Harrison FIELD EXPERIMENTS AND CONTROL , 2005 .

[116]  J. Tyran,et al.  Risk aversion relates to cognitive ability: Preferences or Noise? , 2016 .

[117]  Christos A. Ioannou,et al.  Time preferences and risk aversion: Tests on domain differences , 2016 .