The Paradox of Voter Participation? A Laboratory Study

It is widely believed that rational choice theory is grossly inconsistent with empirical observations about voter turnout. We report the results of an experiment designed to test the voter turnout predictions of the rational choice Palfrey–Rosenthal model of participation with asymmetric information. We find that the three main comparative statics predictions are observed in the data: the size effect, whereby turnout goes down in larger electorates; the competition effect, whereby turnout is higher in elections that are expected to be close; and the underdog effect, whereby voters supporting the less popular alternative have higher turnout rates. We also compare the quantitative magnitudes of turnout to the predictions of Nash equilibrium. We find that there is undervoting for small electorates and overvoting for large electorates, relative to Nash equilibrium. These deviations from Nash equilibrium are consistent with the logit version of Quantal Response Equilibrium, which provides a good fit to the data, and can also account for significant voter turnout in very large elections.

[1]  Thomas R. Palfrey,et al.  Anomalous Behavior in Linear Public Goods Experiments: How Much and Why? , 1993 .

[2]  Stephen Coate,et al.  A Group Rule–Utilitarian Approach to Voter Turnout: Theory and Evidence , 2004 .

[3]  B. Grofman Information, participation, and choice : an economic theory of democracy in perspective , 1994 .

[4]  Jacob K. Goeree,et al.  An Explanation of Anomalous Behavior in Models of Political Participation , 2005, American Political Science Review.

[5]  Arthur Schram,et al.  Voter turnout as a participation game: An experimental investigation , 1996 .

[6]  John Ferejohn,et al.  The Paradox of Not Voting: A Decision Theoretic Analysis , 1974, American Political Science Review.

[7]  T. Palfrey,et al.  Anomalous Behavior in Public Goods Experiments: How Much and Why? , 1997 .

[8]  Thomas R. Palfrey,et al.  A strategic calculus of voting , 1983 .

[9]  F. Winden,et al.  Why people vote: Free riding and the production and consumption of social pressure☆ , 1991 .

[10]  Tamar Kugler,et al.  Preference Uncertainty, Voter Participation and Electoral Efficiency: An Experimental Study , 2003 .

[11]  Thomas R. Palfrey,et al.  The Downsian model of electoral participation: Formal theory and empirical analysis of the constituency size effect , 1987 .

[12]  John C. Harsanyi,et al.  Rule utilitarianism, rights, obligations and the theory of rational behavior , 1980 .

[13]  Esteban F. Klor,et al.  On Public Opinion Polls and Voters' Turnout , 2006 .

[14]  Alvaro Sandroni,et al.  A Theory of Participation in Elections , 2006 .

[15]  J. Sonnemans,et al.  Why people vote: experimental evidence , 1996 .

[16]  Thomas R. Palfrey,et al.  Voter Participation and Strategic Uncertainty , 1985, American Political Science Review.

[17]  T. Cason,et al.  Uncertainty and Resistance to Reform in Laboratory Participation Games , 2005 .

[18]  Michael Boss Economic theory of democracy , 1974 .

[19]  A. Schram,et al.  Neighborhood Information Exchange and Voter Participation: An Experimental Study , 2006, American Political Science Review.

[20]  Alessandra Casella,et al.  An Experimental Study of Storable Votes , 2003 .

[21]  Schenley Park The Downsian model of electoral participation : Formal theory and empirical analysis of the constituency size effect , 2004 .

[22]  H. Rosenthal,et al.  Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 With^ Funding from Testing Game-theoretic Models of Free Riding: New Evidence on Probability Bias and Learning , 2022 .

[23]  M. El-Gamal,et al.  Are People Bayesian? Uncovering Behavioral Strategies , 1995 .