Homo Economicus and Homo Politicus: interpretation and aggregation of environmental values

In addition to his role as a consumer pursuing his own interests, an individual may also regard himself as an ethical observer or citizen, judging matters from society's point of view. However, an individual's personal preferences do not necessarily coincide with his social preferences. This paper presents a formal model in which individuals are assumed to have two distinct preference orderings: Personal well-being functions are applied in contexts where the individual regards himself as a consumer, while subjective social welfare functions are used when the citizen role is perceived as most relevant. The paper discusses the implications for environmental valuation if some respondents take on a citizen role when reporting their willingness to pay.

[1]  Jack L. Knetsch,et al.  Environmental policy implications of disparities between willingness to pay and compensation demanded measures of values , 1990 .

[2]  Rebecca R Boyce An Experimental Examination of Intrinsic Values as a , 1992 .

[3]  K. Arrow,et al.  Social Choice and Individual Values , 1951 .

[4]  Paul Milgrom,et al.  Is Sympathy an Economic Value? Philosophy, Economics, and the Contingent Valuation Method , 1993 .

[5]  A. Freeman,et al.  The measurement of environmental and resource values , 1992 .

[6]  M. Sagoff The Economy of the Earth: Philosophy, Law, and the Environment , 1988 .

[7]  T. Brown,et al.  Moral responsibility effects in valuation of WTA for public and private goods by the method of paired comparison. , 1996 .

[8]  P. Johansson Cost-benefit analysis of environmental change , 1994 .

[9]  A. Sen,et al.  Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory , 1977 .

[10]  Kevin J. Boyle,et al.  Measuring Natural Resource Damages with Contingent Valuation: Tests of Validity and Reliability , 1993 .

[11]  J. Andreoni IMPURE ALTRUISM AND DONATIONS TO PUBLIC GOODS: A THEORY OF WARM-GLOW GIVING* , 1990 .

[12]  K. Nyborg,et al.  Allowing disagreement in evaluations of social welfare , 1996 .

[13]  John W. Payne,et al.  Where Do the Numbers Come From? How People Respond to Contingent Valuation Questions , 1993 .

[14]  Gordon C. Winston Addiction and backsliding: A theory of compulsive consumption , 1980 .

[15]  J. Kelly The Voting Paradox , 1988 .

[16]  Daniel M. Hausman,et al.  Economic analysis and moral philosophy , 1996 .

[17]  Thomas C. Brown,et al.  Information Bias in Contingent Valuation: Effects of Personal Relevance, Quality of Information, and Motivational Orientation , 1996 .

[18]  Daniel Kahneman,et al.  Valuing public goods: The purchase of moral satisfaction , 1992 .

[19]  Howard Margolis,et al.  Selfishness, altruism, and rationality , 1982 .

[20]  A. Vatn,et al.  Choices without Prices without Apologies , 1994 .

[21]  J. Harsanyi Cardinal Welfare, Individualistic Ethics, and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility , 1955 .

[22]  Robert Cameron Mitchell,et al.  Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent Valuation Method , 1989 .

[23]  J. Quiggin,et al.  Respondents To Contingent Valuation Surveys: Consumers Or Citizens? - Reply , 1995 .

[24]  M. O'Connor,et al.  What is the Value of Rangitoto Island? , 1994, Environmental Values.

[25]  Ronald J. Glass,et al.  MEASURING THE EXISTENCE VALUE OF WILDLIFE - WHAT DO CVM ESTIMATES REALLY SHOW , 1991 .

[26]  W. Michael Hanemann,et al.  Valuing the Environment through Contingent Valuation , 1994 .