Re-evaluating the role of energy efficiency standards: : A behavioral economics approach

The economic models that prescribe Pigovian taxation as the first-best means of reducing energy-related externalities are typically based on the neoclassical model of rational consumer choice. Yet, consumer behavior in markets for energy-using durables is generally thought to be far from efficient, giving rise to the concept of the “energy-efficiency gap.” This paper presents a welfare analysis of energy policies that is based on a behavioral model of temptation and self-control, introduced by Gul and Pesendorfer [23,24]. We find that, in the presence of temptation, (i) Pigovian taxes alone do not yield a first-best outcome, (ii) when viewed as substitutes, energy efficiency standards can dominate Pigovian taxes, and (iii) a policy combining standards with a Pigovian tax can yield higher social welfare than a Pigovian tax alone, implying that the two instruments should be viewed as complements rather than substitutes.

[1]  Athanasios C. Thanopoulos,et al.  Social Security Reform with Self-Control Preferences , 2010 .

[2]  Kamhon Kan Cigarette smoking and self-control. , 2007, Journal of health economics.

[3]  Ayelet Fishbach,et al.  Walking the Line between Goals and Temptations: Asymmetric Effects of Counteractive Control , 2010 .

[4]  Winston Harrington,et al.  Should Automobile Fuel Economy Standards be Tightened? , 2007 .

[5]  P. Linares,et al.  Energy Efficiency: Economics and Policy , 2010 .

[6]  Lucas W. Davis Durable goods and residential demand for energy and water: evidence from a field trial , 2008 .

[7]  R. H. Strotz Myopia and Inconsistency in Dynamic Utility Maximization , 1955 .

[8]  Faruk Gul,et al.  Self-control, revealed preference and consumption choice , 2004 .

[9]  R. Thaler,et al.  An Economic Theory of Self-Control , 1977, Journal of Political Economy.

[10]  Anthony A. Smith,et al.  Temptation and Taxation , 2005 .

[11]  Ying Zhang,et al.  Counteractive Construal in Consumer Goal Pursuit , 2010 .

[12]  Jianjun Miao Option exercise with temptation , 2004 .

[13]  S. Mullainathan,et al.  Externalities, Internalities, and the Targeting of Energy Policy , 2012 .

[14]  Anthony A. Smith,et al.  Time orientation and asset prices , 2002 .

[15]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review , 2002 .

[16]  Kenneth A. Small,et al.  Energy Policies for Passenger Motor Vehicles , 2012 .

[17]  Cynthia Barnhart,et al.  Consumption Self-Control by Rationing Purchase Quantities of Virtue and Vice , 1998 .

[18]  Jerry A. Hausman,et al.  Evaluating the costs and benefits of appliance - efficiency standards , 1982 .

[19]  Jess Benhabib,et al.  Present-bias, quasi-hyperbolic discounting, and fixed costs , 2010, Games Econ. Behav..

[20]  David I. Laibson,et al.  Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting , 1997 .

[21]  W. Oates,et al.  Are Energy Efficiency Standards Justified? , 2010 .

[22]  H. Allcott,et al.  The Review of Economics and Statistics , 2014 .

[23]  L. Karp,et al.  Time perspective and climate change policy , 2008 .

[24]  D. N. DeJong,et al.  Do self-control preferences help explain the puzzling behavior of asset prices? , 2007 .

[25]  Jesse M. Shapiro Is There a Daily Discount Rate? Evidence from the Food Stamp Nutrition Cycle , 2003 .

[26]  Richard G. Netemeyer,et al.  Price Perceptions and Consumer Shopping Behavior: A Field Study , 1993 .

[27]  K. Gillingham,et al.  ENERGY EFFICIENCY POLICIES: A Retrospective Examination , 2006 .

[28]  K. Segerson,et al.  Collective voluntary agreements to eliminate polluting products , 2011 .

[29]  Garth Heutel,et al.  Optimal Policy Instruments for Externality-Producing Durable Goods Under Time Inconsistency , 2011 .

[30]  James J Gross,et al.  Harnessing the need for immediate gratification: cognitive reconstrual modulates the reward value of temptations. , 2007, Emotion.

[31]  Faruk Gul,et al.  Temptation and Self‐Control , 1999 .

[32]  Athanasios C. Thanopoulos,et al.  Social Security and Self Control Preferences , 2008 .

[33]  Richard T. Carson,et al.  Discounting behavior and environmental decisions. , 2009 .

[34]  David L. Greene,et al.  Rebound 2007: Analysis of U.S. light-duty vehicle travel statistics , 2012 .

[35]  D. Ariely,et al.  Procrastination, Deadlines, and Performance: Self-Control by Precommitment , 2002, Psychological science.

[36]  Y. Trope,et al.  Counteractive self-control in overcoming temptation. , 2000, Journal of personality and social psychology.

[37]  小林 信治,et al.  自然資源および環境資源への制御理論の適用-解説-上-(Journal of Environmental Economics and Management,4,1977) , 1981 .

[38]  Walter McManus,et al.  The Link Between Gasoline Prices and Vehicle Sales , 2007 .

[39]  K. Segerson,et al.  Temptation as a Factor behind the Energy-Eciency Gap: Some Empirical Evidence , 2012 .

[40]  Nonlinear Pricing with Self-Control Preferences , 2003 .

[41]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Anomalies in Intertemporal Choice: Evidence and an Interpretation , 1992 .

[42]  D. Chapman,et al.  The Kyoto Protocol, Cafe Standards, And Gasoline Taxes , 1999 .

[43]  D. Greene How Consumers Value Fuel Economy: A Literature Review , 2010 .

[44]  Soren T. Anderson,et al.  Automobile Fuel Economy Standards: Impacts, Efficiency, and Alternatives , 2010, Review of Environmental Economics and Policy.

[45]  Mark R. Jacobsen Evaluating US Fuel Economy Standards in a Model with Producer and Household Heterogeneity , 2013 .

[46]  J. Rubin,et al.  Two-Stage Hedonic Price Model for Light-Duty Vehicles , 2010 .

[47]  S. Sorrell,et al.  Empirical estimates of the direct rebound effect: A review , 2009 .

[48]  M. Pycia,et al.  Dynamic inconsistency and self-control: a planner-doer interpretation , 2002 .

[49]  K. Small,et al.  Fuel Efficiency and Motor Vehicle Travel: The Declining Rebound Effect , 2007, Controlling Automobile Air Pollution.

[50]  James M. Sallee,et al.  The Taxation of Fuel Economy , 2010, Tax Policy and the Economy.