Optimal Variety and Pricing Decisions of a Supply Chain With Economies of Scope

Motivated by observations that consumers demand product variety and scope economies or diseconomies for multiple products are prevalent, we develop two supply chain models under different channel leaderships, namely the retailer(-led) Stackelberg (RS) model and manufacturer(-led) Stackelberg (MS) model, to address the issues on product variety and pricing. In the RS case, we find that if it is not too costly to increase variety, the manufacturer's profit increases with diseconomies of scope, and it is optimal to provide a greater variety than the variety just covering the market under the centralized supply chain, while the decentralized supply chain provides a variety level just covering the market; however, the variety under the decentralized supply chain is greater than that under the centralized system. In addition, a higher shelf cost for the retailer strengthens the double marginalization effect. For the MS model, when we compare it with the RS model, we find that the retail price under the MS model is higher than that under the RS model, while the variety level under the MS model is higher when scope economies exist and whether variety and channel profit under the MS model are higher highly depends on shelf cost and marginal variety cost.

[1]  Erik Brynjolfsson,et al.  Consumer Surplus in the Digital Economy: Estimating the Value of Increased Product Variety at Online Booksellers , 2003, Manag. Sci..

[2]  Hon-Shiang Lau,et al.  Pricing and volume discounting for a dominant retailer with uncertain manufacturing cost information , 2007, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[3]  Vijay Mahajan,et al.  An Analysis of Manufacturer-Retailer Supply Chain Coordination in Cooperative Advertising , 2002, Decis. Sci..

[4]  Siemens, Ferdinand von: Bargaining under Incomplete Information, Fairness, and the Hold-Up Problem , 2005 .

[5]  Stephen A. Smith,et al.  Retail Supply Chain Management , 2009 .

[6]  Kin Keung Lai,et al.  Revenue-sharing versus wholesale price mechanisms under different channel power structures , 2010, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[7]  D. Teece ECONOMIES OF SCOPE AND THE SCOPE OF THE ENTERPRISE , 1980 .

[8]  Paul R. Messinger,et al.  Has Power Shifted in the Grocery Channel , 1995 .

[9]  Marshall L. Fisher,et al.  The Impact of Product Variety on Automobile Assembly Operations: Empirical Evidence and Simulation Analysis , 1999 .

[10]  L FisherMarshall,et al.  The Impact of Product Variety on Automobile Assembly Operations , 1999 .

[11]  Sungchul Choi,et al.  Price competition and store competition: Store brands vs. national brand , 2013, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[12]  J. Spengler Vertical Integration and Antitrust Policy , 1950, Journal of Political Economy.

[13]  T. Choi Pre-season stocking and pricing decisions for fashion retailers with multiple information updating , 2007 .

[14]  Nan Xia,et al.  Standard vs. Custom Products: Variety, Lead Time, and Price Competition , 2009, Mark. Sci..

[15]  K. Srinivasan,et al.  Broader product line: a necessity to achieve success? , 1990 .

[16]  Yan Dong,et al.  Efficient replenishment in the distribution channel , 2007 .

[17]  Xuying Zhao,et al.  Optimal Pricing and Capacity Investment for Delay-Sensitive Demand , 2013, IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management.

[18]  R. Willig,et al.  Economies of scope , 1981 .

[19]  Jean-Paul Chavas,et al.  Economies of diversification: A generalization and decomposition of economies of scope , 2010 .

[20]  T. C. Edwin Cheng,et al.  Product variety and channel structure strategy for a retailer-Stackelberg supply chain , 2014, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[21]  I. Simonson,et al.  The Influence of Product Variety on Brand Perception and Choice , 2006 .

[22]  Y. Braunstein,et al.  A Composite Cost Function for Multiproduct Firms with an Application to Economies of Scope in Banking , 1992 .

[23]  Anthony J. Dukes,et al.  Strategic Manufacturer Response to a Dominant Retailer , 2007 .

[24]  Paul M. Griffin,et al.  Supplier- and buyer-driven channels in a two-stage supply chain , 2002 .

[25]  R. Staelin,et al.  Vertical Strategic Interaction: Implications for Channel Pricing Strategy , 1997 .

[26]  M. Parlar,et al.  Lead-time reduction in a two-level supply chain : non-cooperative equilibria vs. coordination with a profit-sharing contract , 2009 .

[27]  Ralph A. Winter Vertical Restraints and Antitrust Policy: A Reaction to Cooper, Froeb, O'Brien, and Vita , 2005 .

[28]  Charles J. Corbett,et al.  Mass Customization vs. Mass Production: Variety and Price Competition , 2008, Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag..

[29]  A. Raman,et al.  The Effect of Product Variety and Inventory Levels on Retail Store Sales: A Longitudinal Study , 2010 .

[30]  Yigal Gerchak,et al.  Supply Chain Coordination when Demand Is Shelf-Space Dependent , 2000, Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag..

[31]  Halil Dundar,et al.  Departmental Productivity in American Universities: Economies of Scale and Scope , 1995 .

[32]  Xiao-Feng Shao,et al.  Integrated Product and Channel Decision in Mass Customization , 2013, IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management.

[33]  Allen M. Featherstone,et al.  Estimating Economies of Scope Using Profit Function: A Dual Approach of the Normalized Quadratic Profit Function , 2006 .

[34]  Samar K. Mukhopadhyay,et al.  Optimal return policy and modular design for build-to-order products , 2005 .

[35]  Taylor Randall,et al.  Product Variety, Supply Chain Structure, and Firm Performance: Analysis of the U.S. Bicycle Industry , 2001, Manag. Sci..

[36]  Gérard P. Cachon,et al.  Competing Manufacturers in a Retail Supply Chain: On Contractual Form and Coordination , 2010, Manag. Sci..

[37]  S. Wallace,et al.  Product variety arising from hedging in the fashion supply chains , 2008 .

[38]  S. Balasubramanian Mail Versus Mall: a Strategic Analysis of Competition Between Direct Marketers and Conventional Retailers , 1998 .

[39]  Robert D. Willig,et al.  Multiproduct Technology and Market Structure , 1979 .