Competition for a Majority

We define the class of two‐player zero‐sum games with payoffs having mild discontinuities, which in applications typically stem from how ties are resolved. For such games, we establish sufficient conditions for existence of a value of the game, maximin and minimax strategies for the players, and a Nash equilibrium. If all discontinuities favor one player, then a value exists and that player has a maximin strategy. A property called payoff approachability implies existence of an equilibrium, and that the resulting value is invariant: games with the same payoffs at points of continuity have the same value and ɛ‐equilibria. For voting games in which two candidates propose policies and a candidate wins election if a weighted majority of voters prefer his proposed policy, we provide tie‐breaking rules and assumptions about voters' preferences sufficient to imply payoff approachability. These assumptions are satisfied by generic preferences if the dimension of the space of policies exceeds the number of voters; or with no dimensional restriction, if the electorate is sufficiently large. Each Colonel Blotto game is a special case in which each candidate allocates a resource among several constituencies and a candidate gets votes from those allocated more than his opponent offers; in this case, for simple‐majority rule we prove existence of an equilibrium with zero probability of ties.

[1]  T. Parthasarathy On Games Over the Unit Square , 1970 .

[2]  B. Roberson,et al.  The non-constant-sum Colonel Blotto game , 2008, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[3]  John Duggan Mixed Strategy Equilibrium and Deep Covering in Multidimensional Electoral Competition Preliminary and Incomplete Do Not Cite , 2004 .

[4]  E. Maskin,et al.  The Existence of Equilibrium in Discontinuous Economic Games, I: Theory , 1986 .

[5]  Jean-François Laslier,et al.  Party objectives in the "Divide a dollar" electoral competition , 2005 .

[6]  B. Roberson The Colonel Blotto game , 2006 .

[7]  Jeroen M. Swinkels,et al.  Existence of Equilibrium in Single and Double Private Value Auctions , 2004 .

[8]  John Duggan,et al.  A dynamic model of democratic elections in multidimensional policy spaces , 2008 .

[9]  E. Maskin,et al.  The Existence of Equilibrium in Discontinuous Economic Games, II: Applications , 1986 .

[10]  John Duggan,et al.  Bounds for Mixed Strategy Equilibria and the Spatial Model of Elections , 2002, J. Econ. Theory.

[11]  W. Zame,et al.  Discontinuous Games and Endogenous Sharing Rules , 1987 .

[12]  Jean-François Laslier,et al.  Distributive Politics and Electoral Competition , 2002, J. Econ. Theory.

[13]  Jean-François Mertens The minmax theorem for U.S.C.-L.S.C. payoff functions , 1986 .

[14]  John Duggan,et al.  Equilibrium existence for zero-sum games and spatial models of elections , 2007, Games Econ. Behav..

[15]  Michael Boss Economic theory of democracy , 1974 .

[16]  Dmitriy Kvasov,et al.  Contests with limited resources , 2007, J. Econ. Theory.

[17]  P. Reny On the Existence of Pure and Mixed Strategy Nash Equilibria in Discontinuous Games , 1999 .

[18]  Jean-François Laslier,et al.  How two-party competition treats minorities , 2002 .

[19]  N. S. Barnett,et al.  Private communication , 1969 .

[20]  Roger B. Myerson,et al.  Bicameralism and Its Consequences for the Internal Organization of Legislatures , 1999 .

[21]  Sergiu Hart,et al.  Discrete Colonel Blotto and General Lotto games , 2008, Int. J. Game Theory.

[22]  Charles R. Plott,et al.  A Notion of Equilibrium and Its Possibility Under Majority Rule , 1967 .

[23]  Philip Wolfe,et al.  Contributions to the theory of games , 1953 .

[24]  D. Blackwell An analog of the minimax theorem for vector payoffs. , 1956 .