The theory of oligopoly price is very sensitive to behavioral assumptions. Even given identical assumptions about costs and demand, different models can predict every price between marginal cost and monopoly. This paper selects a single oligopoly model, and thus predicts a single oligopoly price. The selection criterion is consistency of conjectures; each firm's conjectures about the way other firms react to it will be correct. The two classical oligopoly theories, Bertrand and Cournot, make identical assumptions about costs and demand, but different assumptions about firm behavior. In Cournot equilibrium, each firm maximizes profit given the quantity of output other firms produce. In Bertrand equilibrium, each firm maximizes given the prices other firms charge. This difference in behavioral assumptions leads to a large divergence in predicted prices. Cournot predicts positive markups that decline as the number of firms increases, while Bertrand predicts marginal cost pricing even in duopoly. Clearly both models cannot be correct. Is their truth an empirical question, as recent work suggests?' This paper attempts to decide on theoretical grounds. No attempt to decide among Bertrand, Cournot, and their more modern competitors can be based on mathematical correctness. Economic criteria must guide the decision. Oligopoly models are examples of what game theorists call Nash equilibrium. In them, every firm maximizes profits given the actions of all other firms. The mathematics does not care whether "actions" are defined to be prices (Bertrand), quantities (Cournot), or any other variables. Yet these distinctions are crucial to the economics of the situation. The notion of Nash equilibrium already entails one economic condition-individual rationality. This paper will determine the correct definition of actions by imposing a further economic conditionconsistency of conjectures.2 The precise sense in which conjectures are to be consistent is this; the conjectural variation and the reaction function will be equated. The conjectural variation is the firm's conjecture about other firms' behavior. In Cournot, for example, each firm conjectures that all other firms' quantities are constant. The reaction function is the firm's actual behavior. It is the solution to the profit-maximizing problem, and tells what the firm will do as a function of all other firms' actions. Clearly, what the firm conjectures affects how it reacts. This paper will search for cases where conjectures and reactions are the samewhere each firm's conjectures about other firms' reactions are perfectly correct, locally.3 Every notion of Nash equilibrium has the feature that, in equilibrium, each firm's beliefs about the level of all other firms' actions are confirmed. For example, in Cournot duopoly, each firm's equilibrium quantity is that one which induces the other firm to produce its equilibrium quantity. The firms are right in their beliefs, in Fellner's famous remark, but right for the wrong reason. That is, it is not actually true, as conjectured by the firm, that the other firm's quantity is a constant. The other firm's quantity depends nontrivially on ours-the reaction function does not have zero slope, although the conjecture does. This paper will find Nash equilibrium notions in which firms are right for
[1]
William Fellner,et al.
Competition Among the Few.
,
1952
.
[2]
T. Negishi.
Monopolistic Competition and General Equilibrium
,
1961
.
[3]
L. Telser,et al.
Competition, collusion, and game theory
,
1972
.
[4]
James W. Friedman,et al.
Oligopoly and the theory of games
,
1977
.
[5]
A. Spence.
Entry, Capacity, Investment and Oligopolistic Pricing
,
1977
.
[6]
Yoshio Kimura,et al.
Introduction to mathematical economics
,
1978
.
[7]
Frank Hahn,et al.
On Non-Walrasian Equilibria
,
1978
.
[8]
R. Selten,et al.
Restabilizing Responses, Inertia Supergames, and Oligopolistic Equilibria
,
1978
.
[9]
A. Dixit.
The Role Of Investment In Entry-Deterrence
,
1980
.
[10]
Donald A. Hay,et al.
Industrial Economics: Theory and Evidence
,
1979
.