How Do Prior Outcomes Affect Risk Attitude? Comparing Escalation of Commitment and the House-Money Effect

When making sequential decisions, do prior gains induce more or less risk taking than prior losses? Prior studies have found evidence for a house-money effect, where risk taking increases following gains. These studies also found seemingly contradictory evidence for escalation of commitment, where risk taking increases following losses. We present an experimental study investigating this apparent contradiction. By manipulating the presentation format of a decision problem we can induce both types of behavior. When the problem is presented as a portfolio decision, risk taking is greater following losses than following gains, consistent with escalation of commitment. When the problem is presented as a two-stage betting game, risk taking is greater following gains than following losses, consistent with the house-money effect. Some of these results can be accounted for using the prospect-theory value function. Escalation of commitment in our experiment does not appear to be driven by a need to justify or rationalize the initial decision. These results are potentially relevant to modeling risk preference in multiperiod investment decisions.

[1]  David Johnstone,et al.  Behavioral and Prescriptive Explanations of a Reverse Sunk Cost Effect , 2002 .

[2]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk — Source link , 2007 .

[3]  M. Rabin Risk Aversion and Expected Utility Theory: A Calibration Theorem , 2000 .

[4]  A. Tversky,et al.  BELIEF IN THE LAW OF SMALL NUMBERS , 1971, Pediatrics.

[5]  A. Tversky,et al.  The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. , 1981, Science.

[6]  H. Arkes,et al.  The Psychology of Sunk Cost , 1985 .

[7]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect Theory : An Analysis of Decision under Risk Author ( s ) : , 2007 .

[8]  Barry M. Staw,et al.  Knee-deep in the Big Muddy: A study of escalating commitment to a chosen course of action. , 1976 .

[9]  Mary M. Bange Do the Portfolios of Small Investors Reflect Positive Feedback Trading? , 2000, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis.

[10]  J. Potters,et al.  An experiment on risk taking and evaluation periods , 1997 .

[11]  Martin Weber Decision Making with Incomplete Information , 1987 .

[12]  Mark Grinblatt,et al.  What Makes Investors Trade? , 2000 .

[13]  R. Thaler,et al.  Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: the effects of prior outcomes on risky choice , 1990 .

[14]  M. Statman,et al.  The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long , 1985 .

[15]  Tyler Shumway,et al.  Do Behavioral Biases Affect Prices? , 2001 .

[16]  A. Kapteyn,et al.  Evaluation Periods and Asset Prices in a Market Experiment , 2003 .

[17]  Peter D. Loeb,et al.  Cognitive dissonance and utility maximization: A general framework , 1987 .

[18]  J. Brockner The Escalation of Commitment to a Failing Course of Action: Toward Theoretical Progress , 1992 .

[19]  A. Tversky,et al.  Thinking through uncertainty: Nonconsequential reasoning and choice , 1992, Cognitive Psychology.

[20]  Prospect Theory and Asset Prices , 1999 .

[21]  A. Tversky,et al.  Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty , 1992 .

[22]  Terrance Odean,et al.  Are Investors Reluctant to Realize Their Losses? , 1996 .

[23]  Colin Camerer,et al.  The Disposition Effect in Securities Trading: An Experimental Analysis , 1991 .