Why is the public sector more labor-intensive? A distortionary tax argument

Government-run entities are often more labor-intensive than private companies, even with identical production technologies. This need not imply slack in the public sector, but may reflect a wage tax advantage, stemming from the fact that government entities (partly) pay their taxes to themselves. A tax-induced cost advantage of public production precludes production efficiency and reduces welfare when labor supply is inelastic. With an elastic labor supply, a wage tax advantage of the public sector may improve welfare if it allows for a higher net wage.

[1]  William L. Megginson,et al.  Forthcoming, Journal of Economic Literature FROM STATE TO MARKET: A SURVEY OF EMPIRICAL STUDIES ON PRIVATIZATION , 2000 .

[2]  J. Mirrlees,et al.  Private Constant Returns and Public Shadow Prices , 1976 .

[3]  Florencio López‐de‐Silanes,et al.  The Benefits of Privatization: Evidence from Mexico , 1999 .

[4]  A. Alesina,et al.  Redistributive Public Employment , 1998 .

[5]  William L. Megginson,et al.  The Financial and Operating Performance of Newly Privatized Firms: an International Empirical Analysis , 1994, Estudios de Administración.

[6]  F. Fisher,et al.  Aggregation in Production Functions: What Applied Economists Should Know , 2003 .

[7]  H. Huizinga,et al.  Privatization, Public Investment, and Capital Income Taxation , 1997 .

[8]  Christos Kotsogiannis,et al.  On production efficiency in federal systems , 2002 .

[9]  Jukka Pirttilä,et al.  Public Versus Private Production Decisions: Redistribution and the Size of the Public Sector , 2005 .

[10]  A. Mukherjee,et al.  An International Statistical Survey of Government Employment and Wages , 1999 .

[11]  J. Haltiwanger,et al.  Cross-Country Evidence on Public Sector Retrenchment , 1999 .

[12]  Peter A. Diamond,et al.  Optimal Taxation and Public Production I: Production Efficiency, II: Tax Rules , 1971 .

[13]  Hisahiro Naito Re-examination of uniform commodity taxes under a non-linear income tax system and its implication for production efficiency , 1999 .

[14]  G. Fraja,et al.  Productive efficiency in public and private firms , 1993 .

[15]  Peter A. Diamond,et al.  Optimal taxation and public production , 1968 .

[16]  Kathryn L. Dewenter,et al.  State-Owned and Privately Owned Firms: An Empirical Analysis of Profitability, Leverage, and Labor Intensity , 2001 .

[17]  David S. Saal,et al.  International Handbook on Privatization , 2003 .

[18]  James Barrese Public Finance and Public Policy in the New Century , 2005 .

[19]  Andrei Shleifer,et al.  State Versus Private Ownership , 1998 .

[20]  P. Dasgupta,et al.  Differential Taxation, Public Goods, and Economic Efficiency , 1971 .

[21]  R. Rob,et al.  Working in Public and Private Firms , 2001 .

[22]  R. Gradus,et al.  Contracting out: The importance of a solution for the VAT distortion , 2004 .

[23]  R. Gordon Taxes and Privatization , 2001 .

[24]  Jan-Erik Lane,et al.  New Public Management , 2021, Bangladesh Journal of Public Administration.

[25]  Ellen M. Pint,et al.  Nationalization vs. regulation of monopolies: The effects of ownership on efficiency☆ , 1991 .

[26]  H. Sinn,et al.  Public Finance and Public Policy in the New Century , 2003 .

[27]  P. Sørensen Measuring the tax burden on capital and labor , 2004 .

[28]  P. Dasgupta,et al.  On Optimal Taxation and Public Production , 1972 .

[29]  P. Sørensen The case for international tax co‐ordination reconsidered , 2000 .

[30]  R. Halvorsen,et al.  The relative efficiency of public and private firms in a regulated environment: The case of U.S. electric utilities , 1986 .