Leaving the store empty‐handed: Testing explanations for the too‐much‐choice effect using decision field theory

Economic theories of choice suggest that more options are better, and people should prefer choosing from among more options to find their most valued alternative. But in an intriguing counter-example, Iyengar and Lepper (2000) observed that while people were attracted to more options while shopping, the larger set size increased the likelihood that they would leave the store empty-handed. Surprisingly, this too-much-choice effect has not been consistently observed in situations where it would be expected (e.g., Chernev, 2003; Scheibehenne, 2008). This paper describes boundary conditions for the too-much-choice effect that were determined by evaluating three different psychological explanations within a unified theoretical framework, decision field theory (Busemeyer & Townsend, 1993). The effect of environmental structure on choice was also tested by varying the distribution of quality in the option sets between low variance (roughly uniform) and high variance (exponential distribution). Based on these simulations, two explanations were identified that differentially predicted the too-much-choice effect: avoiding choice when the most preferred option changes too often, or when time runs out. Moreover, the magnitude of the too-much-choice effect depended on the distribution of option quality. These mechanism environment structure combinations can help explain why the too-much-choice effect is observed some—but not all—of the time. © 2009 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.

[1]  U. Hoffrage,et al.  Testing the tyranny of too much choice against the allure of more choice , 2009 .

[2]  R. Hogarth,et al.  Satisfaction in choice as a function of the number of alternatives: When “goods satiate” , 2009 .

[3]  G. Haynes,et al.  Testing the boundaries of the choice overload phenomenon: The effect of number of options and time pressure on decision difficulty and satisfaction , 2009 .

[4]  R. Hertwig,et al.  Size, entropy, and density : What is the difference that makes the difference between small and large real-world assortments? , 2009 .

[5]  P. Todd,et al.  What Moderates the Too-Much-Choice Effect? , 2009 .

[6]  Ryan K. Jessup,et al.  Feedback Produces Divergence From Prospect Theory in Descriptive Choice , 2008, Psychological science.

[7]  B. Scheibehenne The effect of having too much choice , 2008 .

[8]  Joseph Antonik,et al.  Decision Management , 2007, MILCOM 2007 - IEEE Military Communications Conference.

[9]  G. Wolford,et al.  Buying Behavior as a Function of Parametric Variation of Number of Choices , 2007, Psychological science.

[10]  P. Todd,et al.  Escaping the tyranny of choice: when fewer attributes make choice easier , 2007 .

[11]  Jerome R. Busemeyer,et al.  Context effects and models of preferential choice: implications for consumer behavior , 2007 .

[12]  Gordon D. A. Brown,et al.  Decision by sampling , 2006, Cognitive Psychology.

[13]  Joseph G. Johnson,et al.  Preferences constructed from dynamic micro-processing mechanisms , 2006 .

[14]  Joseph G. Johnson,et al.  A dynamic, stochastic, computational model of preference reversal phenomena. , 2005, Psychological review.

[15]  John T. Gourville,et al.  Overchoice and Assortment Type: When and Why Variety Backfires , 2005 .

[16]  B. Schwartz The Paradox of Choice: Why More Is Less , 2004 .

[17]  Byung-Kwan Lee,et al.  The effect of information overload on consumer choice quality in an on-line environment , 2004 .

[18]  A. Chernev When More Is Less and Less Is More: the Role of Ideal Point Availability and Assortment in Consumer Choice This Research Argues That Choices from Different Size Assort- Ments Are a Function of the Degree to Which Consumers Have , 2022 .

[19]  R. Dhar,et al.  The Effect of Forced Choice on Choice , 2003 .

[20]  C. Anderson The Psychology of Doing Nothing: Forms of Decision Avoidance Result from Reason and Emotion , 2003, Psychological bulletin.

[21]  B. Schwartz,et al.  Maximizing versus satisficing: happiness is a matter of choice , 2002 .

[22]  J. Townsend,et al.  Multialternative Decision Field Theory: A Dynamic Connectionist Model of Decision Making , 2001 .

[23]  M. Lepper,et al.  The Construction of Preference: When Choice Is Demotivating: Can One Desire Too Much of a Good Thing? , 2006 .

[24]  M. F. Luce,et al.  Emotional Trade-Off Difficulty and Choice: , 1999 .

[25]  Gerd Gigerenzer,et al.  Fast and frugal heuristics: The adaptive toolbox. , 1999 .

[26]  Ulrich Hoffrage,et al.  Quick estimation : Letting the environment do the work , 1999 .

[27]  B. Kahn,et al.  Variety for sale: Mass customization or mass confusion? , 1998 .

[28]  R. Dhar Consumer Preference for a No-Choice Option , 1997 .

[29]  Diederich,et al.  Dynamic Stochastic Models for Decision Making under Time Constraints , 1997, Journal of mathematical psychology.

[30]  B. Kahn Consumer variety-seeking among goods and services: An integrative review , 1995 .

[31]  J. Townsend,et al.  Decision field theory: a dynamic-cognitive approach to decision making in an uncertain environment. , 1993, Psychological review.

[32]  A. Tversky,et al.  Choice under Conflict: The Dynamics of Deferred Decision , 1992 .

[33]  A. Tversky,et al.  The Disjunction Effect in Choice under Uncertainty , 1992 .

[34]  Eric J. Johnson,et al.  Adaptive Strategy Selection in Decision Making. , 1988 .

[35]  Daniel Kahneman,et al.  Judgment under uncertainty: Availability: A heuristic for judging frequency and probability , 1982 .

[36]  Daniel Kahneman,et al.  Availability: A heuristic for judging frequency and probability , 1973 .

[37]  J. Baron,et al.  An analysis of the word-superiority effect☆ , 1973 .

[38]  A. Tversky Elimination by aspects: A theory of choice. , 1972 .

[39]  C. Hendrick,et al.  Decision time as a function of the number and complexity of equally attractive alternatives. , 1968, Journal of personality and social psychology.

[40]  Yuen Ren Chao,et al.  Human Behavior and the Principle of Least Effort: An Introduction to Human Ecology , 1950 .