Kelly betting can be too conservative

Kelly betting is a prescription for optimal resource allocation among a set of gambles which are typically repeated in an independent and identically distributed manner. In this setting, there is a large body of literature which includes arguments that the theory often leads to bets which are “too aggressive” with respect to various risk metrics. To remedy this problem, many papers include prescriptions for scaling down the bet size. Such schemes are referred to as Fractional Kelly Betting. In this paper, we take the opposite tack. That is, we show that in many cases, the theoretical Kelly-based results may lead to bets which are “too conservative” rather than too aggressive. To make this argument, we consider a random vector X with its assumed probability distribution and draw m samples to obtain an empirically-derived counterpart X̂. Subsequently, we derive and compare the resulting Kelly bets for both X and X̂ with consideration of sample size m as part of the analysis. This leads to identification of many cases which have the following salient feature: The resulting bet size using the true theoretical distribution for X is much smaller than that for X̂. If instead the bet is based on empirical data, “golden” opportunities are identified which are essentially rejected when the purely theoretical model is used. To formalize these ideas, we provide a result which we call the Restricted Betting Theorem. An extreme case of the theorem is obtained when X has unbounded support. In this situation, using X, the Kelly theory can lead to no betting at all.

[1]  Charles W. Therrien,et al.  Probability and Random Processes for Electrical and Computer Engineers , 2011 .

[2]  W. Ziemba,et al.  Growth versus security in dynamic investment analysis , 1992 .

[3]  W. Ziemba Response to Paul a Samuelson Letters and Papers on the Kelly Capital Growth Investment Strategy , 2012 .

[4]  E. Thorp The Kelly Criterion in Blackjack Sports Betting, and the Stock Market , 2008 .

[5]  Mark H. A. Davis,et al.  Fractional Kelly Strategies for Benchmarked Asset Management , 2011 .

[6]  B. Ross Barmish,et al.  On Kelly betting: Some limitations , 2015, 2015 53rd Annual Allerton Conference on Communication, Control, and Computing (Allerton).

[7]  Hans S. Witsenhausen Some aspects of convexity useful in information theory , 1980, IEEE Trans. Inf. Theory.

[8]  D. Luenberger,et al.  Analysis of the rebalancing frequency in log-optimal portfolio selection , 2010 .

[9]  R. C. Merton,et al.  Lifetime Portfolio Selection under Uncertainty: The Continuous-Time Case , 1969 .

[10]  T. Cover,et al.  Asymptotic optimality and asymptotic equipartition properties of log-optimum investment , 1988 .

[11]  Vasily Nekrasov,et al.  Kelly Criterion for Multivariate Portfolios: A Model-Free Approach , 2014 .

[12]  William T. Ziemba,et al.  Long-term capital growth: the good and bad properties of the Kelly and fractional Kelly capital growth criteria , 2010 .

[13]  N. H. Hakansson. ON OPTIMAL MYOPIC PORTFOLIO POLICIES, WITH AND WITHOUT SERIAL CORRELATION OF YIELDS , 1971 .

[14]  Justin K. Rising,et al.  Partial Kelly portfolios and shrinkage estimators , 2012, 2012 IEEE International Symposium on Information Theory Proceedings.

[15]  M. Finkelstein,et al.  Optimal strategies for repeated games , 1981, Advances in Applied Probability.

[16]  William T. Ziemba,et al.  Growth versus security tradeoffs indynamic investment analysis , 1999, Ann. Oper. Res..

[17]  John L. Kelly,et al.  A new interpretation of information rate , 1956, IRE Trans. Inf. Theory.

[18]  E. Thorp,et al.  The Kelly Capital Growth Investment Criterion: Theory and Practice , 2011 .