Nonlinear behavior of the socio-economic dynamics for lake eutrophication control

Abstract To succeed in combating lake eutrophication, cooperation of local inhabitants, small factories, and farmers in reducing phosphorus discharge is very important. But the willingness of each player to cooperate would depend on the cooperation of other players and on the level of environmental concern of the society in general. Here we study the integrated dynamics of people's choice of behavior and the magnitude of eutrophication. Assumptions are: there are a number of players who choose between alternative options: a cooperative and environment-oriented option is more costly than the other. The decision of each player is affected by “social pressure” as well as by economical cost of the options. The lake pollution increases with the total phosphorus released, and a high pollution level in the lake would enhance the social pressure. The model includes a positive and a negative feedback loops which create diverse dynamical behavior. The model often shows bistability — having an equilibrium with a high level of cooperation among people and clean water, and the other equilibrium with low cooperation and polluted water, which are simultaneously stable. The model also shows fluctuation between a high and a low levels of cooperation in alternating years, cycle with a longer periodicity, or chaotic fluctuation. Conservatism of people stabilizes the system and sometimes helps maintaining cooperation. The system may show unexpected parameter dependence — the improved phosphorus removing efficiency might make water more polluted if it causes the decline in the environmental concern and cooperation among people.

[1]  Garry D. Peterson Political ecology and ecological resilience: , 2000 .

[2]  Yoh Iwasa,et al.  Coupled ecological and social dynamics in a forested landscape: the deviation of individual decisions from the social optimum , 2006, Ecological Research.

[3]  R. McKelvey,et al.  Quantal Response Equilibria for Normal Form Games , 1995 .

[4]  Yoh Iwasa,et al.  The leading eight: social norms that can maintain cooperation by indirect reciprocity. , 2006, Journal of theoretical biology.

[5]  Stephen R. Carpenter,et al.  Management of eutrophication for lakes subject to potentially irreversible change , 1999 .

[6]  Stephen R. Carpenter,et al.  Ecological and Social Dynamics in Simple Models of Ecosystem Management , 1999 .

[7]  K. Havens,et al.  Nutrient dynamics and the eutrophication of shallow lakes Kasumigaura (Japan), Donghu (PR China), and Okeechobee (USA). , 2001, Environmental pollution.

[8]  Colin W. Clark,et al.  Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Management of Renewable Resources. , 1993 .

[9]  C. Hauert,et al.  Reward and punishment , 2001, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[10]  S. Carpenter,et al.  Catastrophic regime shifts in ecosystems: linking theory to observation , 2003 .

[11]  M. Pillutla,et al.  Social Norms and Cooperation in Social Dilemmas: The Effects of Context and Feedback. , 1999, Organizational behavior and human decision processes.

[12]  C. Parks,et al.  High And Low Trusters' Responses To Fear in a Payoff Matrix , 1995 .

[13]  Peter Hammerstein,et al.  Game theory and human evolution: a critique of some recent interpretations of experimental games. , 2006, Theoretical population biology.

[14]  Yoh Iwasa,et al.  Coupled ecological-social dynamics in a forested landscape: spatial interactions and information flow. , 2007, Journal of theoretical biology.

[15]  Yoh Iwasa,et al.  How should we define goodness?--reputation dynamics in indirect reciprocity. , 2004, Journal of theoretical biology.

[16]  P. Richerson,et al.  The evolution of indirect reciprocity , 1989 .

[17]  Stephen R. Carpenter,et al.  EUTROPHICATION DUE TO PHOSPHORUS RECYCLING IN RELATION TO LAKE MORPHOMETRY, TEMPERATURE, AND MACROPHYTES , 2005 .

[18]  Florian G. Kaiser,et al.  Responsibility as a predictor of ecological behaviour , 1999 .

[19]  Simon A. Levin,et al.  Fragile Dominion: Complexity and the Commons , 1999 .

[20]  Thomas R. Palfrey,et al.  Testing for effects of cheap talk in a public goods game with private information , 1991 .

[21]  U. Fischbacher,et al.  Are People Conditionally Cooperative? Evidence from a Public Goods Experiment , 2001 .

[22]  T. Gärling,et al.  THE ROLE OF UNCERTAINTY IN RESOURCE DILEMMAS , 1995 .

[23]  R. Boyd,et al.  The evolution of conformist transmission and the emergence of between-group differences. , 1998 .

[24]  Robert Kurzban,et al.  Experiments investigating cooperative types in humans: a complement to evolutionary theory and simulations. , 2005, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[25]  Kimberly E. Medley,et al.  Landscape change with agricultural intensification in a rural watershed, southwestern Ohio, U.S.A. , 1995, Landscape Ecology.

[26]  S. Carpenter Eutrophication of aquatic ecosystems: bistability and soil phosphorus. , 2005, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[27]  E. Fehr,et al.  Collective action as a social exchange , 1999 .

[28]  Y. Iwasa,et al.  The evolution of altruism by costly punishment in lattice-structured populations: score-dependent viability versus score-dependent fertility , 2005 .

[29]  Yoh Iwasa,et al.  The coevolution of altruism and punishment: role of the selfish punisher. , 2006, Journal of theoretical biology.

[30]  T. Gärling,et al.  ENVIRONMENTAL CONCERN: CONCEPTUAL DEFINITIONS, MEASUREMENT METHODS, AND RESEARCH FINDINGS , 1999 .

[31]  S. Carpenter,et al.  NONPOINT POLLUTION OF SURFACE WATERS WITH PHOSPHORUS AND NITROGEN , 1998 .

[32]  M. N,et al.  The Dynamics of Indirect Reciprocity , 1998 .

[33]  C. Keser,et al.  Conditional cooperation and voluntary contributions to public goods , 2000 .