Valuing Money and Things: Why a $20 Item Can be Worth More and Less than $20

The study of risky decision making has long used monetary gambles to study choice, but many everyday decisions do not involve the prospect of winning or losing money. Monetary gambles, as it turns out, may be processed and evaluated differently than gambles with nonmonetary outcomes. Whereas monetary gambles involve numeric amounts that can be straightforwardly combined with probabilities to yield at least an approximate “expectation” of value, nonmonetary outcomes are typically not numeric and do not lend themselves to easy combination with the associated probabilities. Compared with monetary gambles, the evaluation of nonmonetary prospects typically proves less sensitive to changes in the probability range (inside the extremes of certainty and impossibility), which, among other things, can yield preference reversals. Generalizing on earlier work that attributed similar findings to the role of affect in the evaluation process (Rottenstreich, Y., C. K. Hsee. 2001. Money, kisses, and electric shocks: An affective psychology of risk. Psych. Sci.12(3) 185--190), we attribute the observed patterns to a fundamental difference in the evaluation of monetary versus nonmonetary outcomes. Potential pitfalls in the use of monetary gambles to study choice are highlighted, and implications and future directions are discussed.

[1]  Gary L. Wells,et al.  Measuring Psychological Uncertainty : Verbal Versus Numeric Methods , 2004 .

[2]  S. Frederick Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 19, Number 4—Fall 2005—Pages 25–42 Cognitive Reflection and Decision Making , 2022 .

[3]  A. Tversky,et al.  Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty , 1992 .

[4]  A. Tversky,et al.  Weighing Risk and Uncertainty , 1995 .

[5]  K. Vind A foundation for statistics , 2003 .

[6]  Jacob Cohen Statistical Power Analysis for the Behavioral Sciences , 1969, The SAGE Encyclopedia of Research Design.

[7]  Christopher K. Hsee,et al.  Money, Kisses, and Electric Shocks: On the Affective Psychology of Risk , 2001, Psychological science.

[8]  B. Mellers,et al.  Anticipated Emotions as Guides to Choice , 2001 .

[9]  B. Mellers Choice and the relative pleasure of consequences. , 2000, Psychological bulletin.

[10]  Michael H. Birnbaum,et al.  How to show that 9 > 221 : Collect judgments in a between-subjects design , 1999 .

[11]  A. Tversky,et al.  Rational choice and the framing of decisions , 1990 .

[12]  A. Tversky,et al.  Choices, Values, and Frames , 2000 .

[13]  H. Kunreuther,et al.  A Policy Maker’s Dilemma: Preventing Terrorism or Preventing Blame , 2011 .

[14]  Yuval Rottenstreich,et al.  On decision making without likelihood judgment. , 2006 .

[15]  E. Weber From Subjective Probabilities to Decision Weights: The Effect of Asymmetric Loss Functions on the Evaluation of Uncertain Outcomes and Events , 1994 .

[16]  A. Tversky,et al.  Loss Aversion in Riskless Choice: A Reference-Dependent Model , 1991 .

[17]  P. Tetlock,et al.  The Limits of Fungibility: Relational Schemata and the Value of Things , 2003 .

[18]  Michael H. Birnbaum,et al.  A change-of-process theory for contextual effects and preference reversals in risky decision making , 1992 .

[19]  A. K. Basu A Theory of Decision-Making , 1973, The Journal of Sociology & Social Welfare.

[20]  Christopher K. Hsee,et al.  The Evaluability Hypothesis: An Explanation for Preference Reversals between Joint and Separate Evaluations of Alternatives , 1996 .

[21]  George Wu,et al.  The uncertainty effect: When a risky prospect is valued less than its worst possible outcome , 2006 .

[22]  D. Bernoulli Exposition of a New Theory on the Measurement of Risk , 1954 .

[23]  Ian J. Bateman,et al.  The Affect Heuristic and the Attractiveness of Simple Gambles , 2007 .

[24]  Eldar Shafir,et al.  Deep thoughts and shallow frames; on the susceptibility to framing effects. , 2003 .

[25]  Alex B. Markle,et al.  An Empirical Test of Gain-Loss Separability in Prospect Theory , 2008, Manag. Sci..

[26]  M. Allais Le comportement de l'homme rationnel devant le risque : critique des postulats et axiomes de l'ecole americaine , 1953 .

[27]  N. Pennington,et al.  Explanation-based decision making: effects of memory structure on judgment , 1988 .

[28]  D. Ellsberg Decision, probability, and utility: Risk, ambiguity, and the Savage axioms , 1961 .

[29]  Timothy D. Wilson,et al.  Telling more than we can know: Verbal reports on mental processes. , 1977 .

[30]  Joseph C. Nunes,et al.  Using Combined-Currency Prices to Lower Consumers’ Perceived Cost , 2004 .

[31]  A. Tversky,et al.  Compatibility effects in judgment and choice. , 1990 .

[32]  Ilana Ritov,et al.  Economic Preferences or Attitude Expressions?: An Analysis of Dollar Responses to Public Issues , 1999 .

[33]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Recent developments in modeling preferences: Uncertainty and ambiguity , 1992 .

[34]  Eric J. Johnson,et al.  The adaptive decision maker , 1993 .

[35]  Christopher K. Hsee,et al.  Risk as Feelings , 2001, Psychological bulletin.

[36]  J. Cacioppo,et al.  The need for cognition. , 1982 .

[37]  Robert W. Proctor,et al.  Stimulus-Response Compatibility: An Integrated Perspective , 1990 .

[38]  J. P. Morgan,et al.  Design and Analysis: A Researcher's Handbook , 2005, Technometrics.

[39]  A. Tversky,et al.  A Belief-Based Account of Decision Under Uncertainty , 1998 .

[40]  L. J. Savage,et al.  The Foundation of Statistics , 1956 .

[41]  A. Sockloff,et al.  Statistical power analysis for the behavioral sciences: (revised edition), by Jacob Cohen. New York: Academic Press, 1977, xv + 474 pp., $24.50. , 1978 .

[42]  G. Berns,et al.  A shocking experiment: New evidence on probability weighting and common ratio violations , 2007, Judgment and Decision Making.

[43]  James G. March,et al.  A primer on decision making : how decisions happen , 1994 .

[44]  Joseph C. Nunes,et al.  Incommensurate Resources: Not Just More of the Same , 2003 .

[45]  Peter P. Wakker,et al.  On the Intuition of Rank-Dependent Utility , 2000 .

[46]  K. MacCrimmon,et al.  Utility Theory: Axioms Versus ‘Paradoxes’ , 1979 .

[47]  C. K. Mertz,et al.  PSYCHOLOGICAL SCIENCE Research Article Numeracy and Decision Making , 2022 .

[48]  A. Tversky,et al.  Contingent weighting in judgment and choice , 1988 .

[49]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk — Source link , 2007 .

[50]  D. Ariely,et al.  “Coherent Arbitrariness”: Stable Demand Curves Without Stable Preferences , 2003 .

[51]  Yaacov Trope,et al.  Probability as a psychological distance: Construal and preferences , 2007 .

[52]  Christopher K. Hsee,et al.  Music, Pandas, and Muggers: On the Affective Psychology of Value , 2004, Journal of experimental psychology. General.

[53]  Christopher K. Hsee,et al.  When Is More Better? , 2005 .

[54]  Paul Slovic,et al.  The affect heuristic , 2007, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[55]  John W. Payne,et al.  The adaptive decision maker: Name index , 1993 .

[56]  Kevin J. Boyle,et al.  Measuring Natural Resource Damages with Contingent Valuation: Tests of Validity and Reliability , 1993 .

[57]  Max H. Bazerman,et al.  The Construction of Preference: Preference Reversals Between Joint and Separate Evaluations of Options: A Review And Theoretical Analysis , 2006 .

[58]  J. Neumann,et al.  Theory of games and economic behavior , 1945, 100 Years of Math Milestones.

[59]  P. Slovic The Construction of Preference , 1995 .

[60]  G. Keppel Design and analysis: A researcher's handbook, 3rd ed. , 1991 .

[61]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect theory: analysis of decision under risk , 1979 .

[62]  R. Duncan Luce,et al.  Rank- and sign-dependent linear utility models for binary gambles , 1991 .

[63]  M. Allais,et al.  Criticism of the postulates and axioms of the American School. , 1990 .

[64]  P. Slovic,et al.  The Construction of Preference: Index , 2006 .

[65]  Eldar Shafir,et al.  Reason-based choice , 1993, Cognition.