Norms, Coordination, and Order

The dissemination of knowledge is crucial in society. People live in a world of expectations about interactions with others’ actions. It is meaningful to discuss the social order only when all agents share the same perception of existing reality which includes others’ actions. People follow rules of behavior in society. Relying on rules is a device we have learned to use because our reason is insufficient to master the detail of complex reality. If rules are recognized as recurrent patterns of behavior, individuals act according to rules of conduct. The diffusion of shared behavioral patterns is necessary to obtain the social order. Shared rules facilitate the decision-making in complex situations by limiting the range of circumstances to which individuals have to pay attention.

[1]  F. Hayek New studies in philosophy, politics, economics, and the history of ideas , 1978 .

[2]  Peter J. Boettke,et al.  Converting social conflict: Focal points and the evolution of cooperation , 2006 .

[3]  Adam Brandenburger,et al.  Knowledge and Equilibrium in Games , 1992 .

[4]  Sheri M Markose,et al.  Computability and Evolutionary Complexity: Markets as Complex Adaptive Systems (CAS) , 2005 .

[5]  D. Klein Convention, Social Order, and the Two Coordinations , 1997 .

[6]  Nicolai J. Foss,et al.  The limits to designed orders: Authority under “distributed knowledge” conditions , 2006 .

[7]  Herbert A. Simon,et al.  Public Administration in Today's World of Organizations and Markets , 2000, PS: Political Science & Politics.

[8]  R. Sugden Normative judgments and spontaneous order: The contractarian element in Hayek's thought , 1993 .

[9]  R. Sugden A Theory of Focal Points , 1995 .

[10]  R. Cooper,et al.  Coordination Games: Technological Complementarities , 1999 .

[11]  The Legacy of Max Weber , 1971 .

[12]  J. B. Rosser,et al.  Emergence and complexity in Austrian economics , 2012 .

[13]  P. Lewis Emergent Properties in the Work of Friedrich Hayek , 2012 .

[14]  Brian Skyrms,et al.  Signals: Evolution, Learning, and Information , 2010 .

[15]  T. Schelling The Strategy of Conflict , 1963 .

[16]  Peter J. Boettke Information and Knowledge: Austrian Economics in Search of its Uniqueness , 2002 .

[17]  Israel M. Kirzner Entrepreneurial Discovery and the Competitive Market Process: An Austrian Approach , 1997 .

[18]  R. Aumann Agreeing to disagree. , 1976, Nature cell biology.

[19]  L. Lachmann From Mises to Shackle: An Essay on Austrian Economics and the Kaleidic Society , 1976 .

[20]  Robert Sugden,et al.  COMMON KNOWLEDGE, SALIENCE AND CONVENTION: A RECONSTRUCTION OF DAVID LEWIS' GAME THEORY , 2003, Economics and Philosophy.

[21]  J. Cottingham LAW, LEGISLATION AND LIBERTY , 1978 .

[22]  Stuart A. Kauffman,et al.  The origins of order , 1993 .

[23]  Andrew John,et al.  Coordinating Coordination Failures in Keynesian Models , 1988 .

[24]  Adam Brandenburger,et al.  The Role of Common Knowledge Assumptions in Game Theory , 1989 .

[25]  P. Lewis Notions of Order and Process in Hayek: The Significance of Emergence , 2014 .

[26]  Viktor Vanberg Corporate social responsibility and the ‘game of catallaxy’: the perspective of constitutional economics , 2007 .

[27]  Peter G. Klein,et al.  The collected works of F , 1989 .

[28]  博 太郎丸 <書評> Robert Sugden, "The economics of rights, co-operation and welfare", Oxford : Basil Blackwell, 1986 , 1992 .

[29]  Adam Gifford,et al.  The Evolution of the Social Contract , 2002 .

[30]  J M Smith,et al.  Evolution and the theory of games , 1976 .

[31]  David Lewis Convention: A Philosophical Study , 1986 .

[32]  J. Foster Why Is Economics Not a Complex Systems Science? , 2006 .

[33]  Vincent P. Crawford,et al.  A Survey of Experiments on Communication via Cheap Talk , 1998 .

[34]  Friedrich A. von Hayek,et al.  Knowledge, evolution, and society , 1983 .