Performance Measure Congruity and Diversity in Multi-Task Principal/Agent Relations

SYNOPSIS AND INTRODUCTION: Accounting numbers are frequently used in evaluating management performance, and performance evaluation is an important ingredient in motivating managers. Three significant factors generally create difficulties in developing performance measures for a given manager. First, the actions and strategies implemented by the manager are not observable directly, so the manager cannot be compensated directly for his input into the firm. Second, the full consequences of the manager's actions are not observable, in large part because the impact of those actions extend beyond his subunit of the firm and beyond his time as managerof that subunit. Third, uncontrollable events influence the consequences that are observed. The agency theory literature has explored extensively the implications of the nonobservability of the manager's actions and the fact that performance measures are influenced by unobservable, uncontrollable events. However, this literature has given only limited attention to the fact that performance measures frequently are incomplete or imperfect representations of the economic consequences of the manager's actions.1 On the other hand, discussions of performance evaluation in management accounting texts often raise issues regarding the incompleteness and imperfectness of the accounting numbers that are used as performance measures. For example,

[1]  Abbie J. Smith,et al.  An Empirical-Investigation Of The Relative Performance Evaluation Of Corporate-Executives , 1986 .

[2]  Stanley Baiman,et al.  NONCONTROLLABLE COSTS AND RESPONSIBILITY ACCOUNTING , 1985 .

[3]  J. Paul On the Efficiency of Stock-Based Compensation , 1992 .

[4]  Rajiv D. Banker,et al.  Sensitivity, Precision, and Linear Aggregation of Signals for Performance Evaluation , 1989 .

[5]  Bengt Holmstrom,et al.  Moral Hazard in Teams , 1982 .

[6]  John S. Hughes,et al.  Multiple Signals, Statistical Sufficiency, and Pareto Orderings of Best Agency Contracts , 1989 .

[7]  Paul R. Milgrom,et al.  Multitask Principal–Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership, and Job Design , 1991 .

[8]  Ronald A. Dye,et al.  EARNINGS MANAGEMENT IN AN OVERLAPPING GENERATIONS MODEL , 1988 .

[9]  Paul R. Milgrom,et al.  AGGREGATION AND LINEARITY IN THE PROVISION OF INTERTEMPORAL INCENTIVES , 1987 .

[10]  R. Magee Advanced managerial accounting , 1986 .

[11]  R. Dye DISCLOSURE OF NONPROPRIETARY INFORMATION , 1985 .

[12]  John Dickhaut,et al.  Escalation Errors and the Sunk Cost Effect: An Explanation Based on Reputation and Information Asymmetries , 1989 .

[13]  Charles T. Horngren,et al.  Student guide and review manual, Cost accounting : a managerial emphasis, seventh edition, [by] Charles T. Horngren, George Foster , 1991 .

[14]  Amin H. Amershi Blackwell Informativeness and Sufficient Statistics with Applications to Financial Markets and Multiperson Agencies , 1988 .

[15]  E. M. Matsumura Sequential Choice Under Moral Hazard , 1988 .

[16]  Frøystein Gjesdal,et al.  ACCOUNTING FOR STEWARDSHIP , 1981 .

[17]  Robert S. Kaplan,et al.  Advanced Management Accounting , 1989 .

[18]  Madhav V. Rajan,et al.  Cost Accounting: A Managerial Emphasis , 1972 .

[19]  Sanford J. Grossman,et al.  AN ANALYSIS OF THE PRINCIPAL-AGENT PROBLEM , 1983 .

[20]  Raffi J. Indjejikian,et al.  Accounting income, stock price, and managerial compensation , 1993 .

[21]  Frøystein Gjesdal,et al.  Information and Incentives: The Agency Information Problem , 1982 .

[22]  R. Anthony,et al.  Management Control Systems , 2020, Management Control Systems and Tools for Internationalization Success.

[23]  J. Ortega Matrix Theory: A Second Course , 1987 .

[24]  H. Raiffa,et al.  Applied Statistical Decision Theory. , 1961 .

[25]  吳安妮 管理控制系統[Anthony Dearden & Govindarajan,⋘Management Control Systems⋙] , 1992 .