Identification of influencers through the wisdom of crowds

Identifying individuals who are influential in diffusing information, ideas or products in a population remains a challenging problem. Most extant work can be abstracted by a process in which researchers first decide which features describe an influencer and then identify them as the individuals with the highest values of these features. This makes the identification dependent on the relevance of the selected features and it still remains uncertain if triggering the identified influencers leads to a behavioral change in others. Furthermore, most work was developed for cross-sectional or time-aggregated datasets, where the time-evolution of influence processes cannot be observed. We show that mapping the influencer identification to a wisdom of crowds problem overcomes these limitations. We present a framework in which the individuals in a social group repeatedly evaluate the contribution of other members according to what they perceive as valuable and not according to predefined features. We propose a method to aggregate the behavioral reactions of the members of the social group into a collective judgment that considers the temporal variation of influence processes. Using data from three large news providers, we show that the members of the group surprisingly agree on who are the influential individuals. The aggregation method addresses different sources of heterogeneity encountered in social systems and leads to results that are easily interpretable and comparable within and across systems. The approach we propose is computationally scalable and can be applied to any social systems where behavioral reactions are observable.

[1]  Maxi San Miguel,et al.  A measure of individual role in collective dynamics , 2010, Scientific Reports.

[2]  Jon Kleinberg,et al.  Maximizing the spread of influence through a social network , 2003, KDD '03.

[3]  T. Valente Network Interventions , 2012, Science.

[4]  Damon Centola,et al.  Network dynamics of social influence in the wisdom of crowds , 2017, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[5]  N. Christakis,et al.  Social network targeting to maximise population behaviour change: a cluster randomised controlled trial , 2015, The Lancet.

[6]  Seymour Sudman,et al.  Overlap of Opinion Leadership across Consumer Product Categories , 1971 .

[7]  Bernard M. Bass,et al.  An analysis of the leaderless group discussion. , 1949 .

[8]  D. Watts,et al.  Influentials, Networks, and Public Opinion Formation , 2007 .

[9]  Hernán A. Makse,et al.  Influence maximization in complex networks through optimal percolation , 2015, Nature.

[10]  Felix Elwert Public health: real-world network targeting of interventions , 2015, The Lancet.

[11]  Renaud Lambiotte,et al.  Rich gets simpler , 2016, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[12]  D. Leonard-Barton,et al.  Experts as Negative Opinion Leaders in the Diffusion of a Technological Innovation , 1985 .

[13]  H. Sebastian Seung,et al.  A solution to the single-question crowd wisdom problem , 2017, Nature.

[14]  D. Helbing,et al.  How social influence can undermine the wisdom of crowd effect , 2011, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[15]  Daniel L. Sherrell,et al.  Influentials and Influence Mechanisms in New Product Diffusion: An Integrative Review , 2014 .

[16]  Michael Trusov,et al.  Determining Influential Users in Internet Social Networks , 2010 .

[17]  J. Goldenberg,et al.  The Role of Hubs in the Adoption Process , 2009 .

[18]  L. Freeman Centrality in social networks conceptual clarification , 1978 .

[19]  Albert,et al.  Emergence of scaling in random networks , 1999, Science.

[20]  Elihu Katz,et al.  The Diffusion of an Innovation among Physicians1 , 1977 .

[21]  Thomas W. Valente,et al.  Opinion Leadership and Social Contagion in New Product Diffusion , 2011, Mark. Sci..

[22]  Sinan Aral,et al.  Identifying Influential and Susceptible Members of Social Networks , 2012, Science.

[23]  S. Bikhchandani,et al.  You have printed the following article : A Theory of Fads , Fashion , Custom , and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades , 2007 .

[24]  Jari Saramäki,et al.  Exploring temporal networks with greedy walks , 2015, ArXiv.

[25]  F. Galton Vox Populi , 1907, Nature.

[26]  O. Hinz Social Contagion – An Empirical Comparison of Seeding Strategies for Viral Marketing , 2011 .

[27]  Lev Muchnik,et al.  Identifying influential spreaders in complex networks , 2010, 1001.5285.

[28]  P. Bonacich Power and Centrality: A Family of Measures , 1987, American Journal of Sociology.

[29]  Glenn Lawyer,et al.  Understanding the influence of all nodes in a network , 2015, Scientific Reports.

[30]  H. Simon,et al.  ON A CLASS OF SKEW DISTRIBUTION FUNCTIONS , 1955 .

[31]  Arun G. Chandrasekhar,et al.  The Diffusion of Microfinance , 2012, Science.

[32]  L. D. Costa,et al.  Accessibility in complex networks , 2008 .

[33]  Jan U. Becker,et al.  Seeding Strategies for Viral Marketing: An Empirical Comparison , 2011 .

[34]  Petter Holme,et al.  Modern temporal network theory: a colloquium , 2015, The European Physical Journal B.

[35]  Arkadiusz Stopczynski,et al.  Fundamental structures of dynamic social networks , 2015, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[36]  G. Yule,et al.  A Mathematical Theory of Evolution Based on the Conclusions of Dr. J. C. Willis, F.R.S. , 1925 .