From the Horse's Mouth: Economic Conditions and Investor Expectations of Risk and Return

Data obtained from monthly Gallup/UBS surveys from 1998 to 2007 and from a special supplement to the Michigan Surveys of Consumer Attitudes and Behavior, run in 22 monthly surveys between 2000 and 2005, are used to analyze stock market beliefs and portfolio choices of household investors. We show that the key variables found to be positive predictors of actual stock returns in the asset-pricing literature are also highly correlated with investor's subjective expected returns, but with the opposite sign. Moreover, our analysis of the microdata indicates that subjective expectations of both risk and returns on stocks are strongly influenced by perceptions of economic conditions. In particular, when investors believe macroeconomic conditions are more expansionary, they tend to expect both higher returns and lower volatility. This is difficult to reconcile with the canonical view that expected returns on stocks rise during recessions to compensate household investors for increased exposure or sensitivity to macroeconomic risks. Finally, the relevance of these investors' subjective expectations is supported by the finding of a significant link between their expectations and portfolio choices. In particular, we show that portfolio equity positions tend to be higher for those respondents that anticipate higher expected returns or lower uncertainty. This paper was accepted by Brad Barber, finance.

[1]  S. Zeldes,et al.  How do household portfolio shares vary with age? Unpub-lished working paper , 2000 .

[2]  Michael T. Cliff,et al.  Investor Sentiment and Asset Valuation , 2001 .

[3]  Ivo Welch,et al.  Investor Sentiment Measures , 2004 .

[4]  J. Poterba,et al.  Speculative Dynamics and the Role of Feedback Traders , 1990 .

[5]  Darrell Duffie,et al.  Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers , 1996, Journal of Political Economy.

[6]  A. Tversky,et al.  Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases , 1974, Science.

[7]  A. Deaton Consumption , Aggregate Wealth , and Expected Stock Returns , 2008 .

[8]  Ravi Bansal,et al.  Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles , 2000 .

[9]  Michael Lemmon,et al.  Consumer Confidence and Asset Prices: Some Empirical Evidence , 2002 .

[10]  Terrance Odean,et al.  Learning to Be Overconfident , 1997 .

[11]  Hersh Shefrin,et al.  Making Sense of Beta, Size, and Book-to-Market , 1995 .

[12]  Affect in a Behavioral Asset-Pricing Model , 2008 .

[13]  Thomas Langer,et al.  Framing Effects in Stock Market Forecasts: The Difference Between Asking for Prices and Asking for Returns , 2007 .

[14]  E. Weber,et al.  A Domain-Specific Risk-Attitude Scale: Measuring Risk Perceptions and Risk Behaviors , 2002 .

[15]  Charles F. Manski,et al.  How Should We Measure Consumer Confidence , 2004 .

[16]  E. Fama,et al.  BUSINESS CONDITIONS AND EXPECTED RETURNS ON STOCKS AND BONDS , 1989 .

[17]  Ning Zhu,et al.  Do Retail Trades Move Markets , 2009 .

[18]  Brad M. Barber,et al.  Boys Will Be Boys: Gender, Overconfidence, and Common Stock Investment , 1998 .

[19]  Avanidhar Subrahmanyam,et al.  Behavioral Finance: A Review and Synthesis , 2007 .

[20]  R. Thaler,et al.  A Survey of Behavioral Finance , 2002 .

[21]  J. Heaton,et al.  Portfolio Choice and Asset Prices: The Importance of Entrepreneurial Risk , 2000 .

[22]  A. Lo,et al.  THE ECONOMETRICS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS , 1996, Macroeconomic Dynamics.

[23]  A. Shleifer,et al.  Expectations of Returns and Expected Returns , 2013 .

[24]  Markus K. Brunnermeier,et al.  Do Wealth Fluctuations Generate Time-Varying Risk Aversion? Micro-Evidence on Individuals' Asset Allocation , 2008 .

[25]  Paul Slovic,et al.  The affect heuristic , 2007, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[26]  Kenneth L. Fisher,et al.  Blowing Bubbles , 2002 .

[27]  S. Davis,et al.  Risky Labor Income and Portfolio Choice , 2001 .

[28]  Markus K. Brunnermeier,et al.  Do Wealth Fluctuations Generate Time-Varying Risk Aversion? Micro-Evidence on Individuals' Asset Allocation , 2005 .

[29]  L. Summers,et al.  Positive Feedback Investment Strategies and Destabilizing Rational Speculation , 1989 .

[30]  L. Hamilton How Robust is Robust Regression , 1992 .

[31]  P. Samuelson LIFETIME PORTFOLIO SELECTION BY DYNAMIC STOCHASTIC PROGRAMMING , 1969 .

[32]  Markus K. Brunnermeier,et al.  Hedge Funds and the Technology Bubble , 2003 .

[33]  M. Statman Investor Sentiment and Stock Returns , 1999 .

[34]  Reuven Lehavy,et al.  Using Expectations to Test Asset Pricing Models , 2003 .

[35]  John R. Nofsinger,et al.  Herding and Feedback Trading by Institutional and Individual Investors , 1999 .

[36]  Werner F. M. De Bondt,et al.  Betting on trends: Intuitive forecasts of financial risk and return , 1993 .

[37]  Rui Yao,et al.  Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Choices with Risky Housing and Borrowing Constraints , 2004 .

[38]  I. Welch,et al.  A Comprehensive Look at the Empirical Performance of Equity Premium Prediction II , 2004, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[39]  R. Stambaugh,et al.  Predictive Regressions , 1999 .

[40]  Baruch Fischhoff,et al.  What Number is “Fifty‐Fifty”?: Redistributing Excessive 50% Responses in Elicited Probabilities , 2002, Risk analysis : an official publication of the Society for Risk Analysis.

[41]  Ulrike Malmendier,et al.  Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? , 2009 .

[42]  J. Campbell,et al.  By Force of Habit: A Consumption‐Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.