Using Experiments to Inform the Privatization/Deregulation Movement in Electricity

At the University of Arizona, electronic trading (now commonly known as e-commerce) in the experimental laboratory began in 1976 when Arlington Williams conducted the initial experiments testing the first electronic "double-auction" trading system, which he had programmed on the Plato operating system. The term "double auction" refers to the oral bid-ask sequential trading system used since the 19th century in stock and commodity trading on the organized exchanges. This system of trading has been used in economics experiments since the 1950s, and is extremely robust in yielding convergence to competitive equilibrium outcomes (Smith 1962, 1982a). Since information on what buyers are willing to pay, and sellers are willing to accept, is dispersed and strictly private in these experiments, the convergence results have been interpreted (Smith 1982b) as supporting F.A. Hayek's thesis "that the most significant fact about this (price) system is the economy of knowledge with which it operates, or how little the individual participants need to know in order to be able to take the right action" (Hayek 1945: 526-27). As with all first efforts at automation, the software developed by Williams allowed double-auction trading experiments that previously had kept manual records of oral bids, asks and trades, to be computerized. (1) That is, it facilitated real-time public display of participant messages, recording of data, and greater experimental control of a process defined by preexisting technology. It did not modify that technology in fundamental ways. This event unleashed a discovery process commonplace in the history of institutional change: the joining of a new technology to an incumbent institution causes entirely new, heretofore unimaginable institutions to be created spontaneously, as individuals are motivated to initiate procedural changes in the light of the new technology. Electronic exchange made it possible to vastly reduce transactions cost--the time and search costs required to match buyers and sellers, to negotiate trades, including agreements to supply transportation and other support services. More subtly it enabled this matching to occur on vastly more complicated message spaces, and allowed optimization and other processing algorithms to be applied to messages, facilitating efficient trades among agents that had been too costly to be consummated with older technologies. Moreover, resource allocation problems thought to require hierarchical command and control forms of coordination, as in regulated pipeline and electric power networks, became easily susceptible to self-regulation by entirely new decentralized pricing and property right regimes. Coordination economies in complex networks could be achieved at low transactions cost by independent agents, with dispersed information, integrated by a computerized market mechanism. This realization then laid the basis for a new class of experiments in which the laboratory is used to test-bed proposed new market mechanisms to enable a better understanding of how such mechanisms might function in the field, and to create a demonstration and training tool for potential participants and practitioners who become part of the "proving" process. Of course, once adopted, this modification and proving process continues in light of field experience. We provide a short history of the application of the conception of smart computer assisted markets to the design of electricity markets here and abroad. The Privatization/Deregulation Movement in Electricity We use the term "privatization" to describe generically the process of reform of foreign government command forms of organization of the electric industry. In all cases major components of the industry have not had their ownership transferred from public to private entities. Reform has focused on the use of decentralized spot and futures markets to provide price signals to improve the short and longer term management of the industry. …

[1]  V. Smith ELECTRIC POWER DEREGULATION: BACKGROUND AND PROSPECTS , 1988 .

[2]  Avraham Steinberg,et al.  Allocation of scarce resources. , 1995, Assia--Jewish medical ethics.

[3]  G. Stern,et al.  Simultaneous Optimal Auction and Unit Commitment for Deregulated Electricity Markets , 2002 .

[4]  S. Rassenti,et al.  Cotenancy and competition in an experimental auction market for natural gas pipeline networks , 1994 .

[5]  S. Rassenti,et al.  Oligopoly competition in fixed cost environments , 2004 .

[6]  Vernon L. Smith,et al.  Papers in Experimental Economics: Markets as Economizers of Information: Experimental Examination of the “Hayek Hypothesis” , 1991 .

[7]  E. Duflo,et al.  The Role of Information and Social Interactions in Retirement Plan Decisions: Evidence from a Randomized Experiment , 2002 .

[8]  Vernon L. Smith Regulatory Reform in the Electric Power Industry , 1996 .

[9]  Vernon L. Smith,et al.  Markets as Economizers of Information: Experimental Examination of the Hayek , 1982 .

[10]  Stephen J. Rassenti,et al.  Market power in a deregulated electrical industry , 2001, Decis. Support Syst..

[11]  Stephen J. Rassenti,et al.  Market design and motivated human trading behavior in electricity markets , 1999, Proceedings of the 32nd Annual Hawaii International Conference on Systems Sciences. 1999. HICSS-32. Abstracts and CD-ROM of Full Papers.

[12]  Stephen J. Rassenti,et al.  Can core allocations be achieved in avoidable fixed cost environments using two-part price competition? , 1996, Ann. Oper. Res..

[13]  J. Mcmillan Managing Economic Change: Lessons from New Zealand , 1998 .

[14]  S. Rosen Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation in Pure Competition , 1974, Journal of Political Economy.

[15]  Arlington Williams,et al.  Computerized Double-Auction Markets: Some Initial Experimental Results , 1980 .

[16]  V. Smith Microeconomic Systems as an Experimental Science , 1982 .

[17]  Charles A. Holt The Exercise of Market Power in Laboratory Experiments , 1989, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[18]  R. J. Kaye,et al.  A Theory of Electricity Tariff Design for Optimal Operation and Investment , 1989, IEEE Power Engineering Review.

[19]  Robert Forsythe,et al.  Demand-Revealing Mechanisms for Private Good Auctions , 1980 .

[20]  Stephen J. Rassenti,et al.  Auction design for composite goods : The natural gas industry , 1990 .

[21]  S. Rassenti,et al.  A Combinatorial Auction Mechanism for Airport Time Slot Allocation , 1982 .

[22]  Paul R. Kleindorfer,et al.  Ownership Structure, Contracting and Regulation of Transmission Services Providers , 1998 .

[23]  V. Smith An Experimental Study of Competitive Market Behavior , 1962, Journal of Political Economy.

[24]  Bart J. Wilson,et al.  Controlling market power and price spikes in electricity networks: Demand-side bidding , 2003, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[25]  Stephen J. Rassenti,et al.  Efficiency and Income Shares in High-Demand Energy Networks: Who Receives the Congestion Rents when a Line is Constrained? , 2000 .

[26]  Transmission Pricing and Stranded Costs in the Electric Power Industry , 1995 .

[27]  S. Borenstein The Trouble With Electricity Markets: Understanding California's Restructuring Disaster , 2002 .

[28]  Stephen J. Rassenti,et al.  Spot market mechanism design and competitivity issues in electric power , 1998, Proceedings of the Thirty-First Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences.

[29]  Nathaniel T. Wilcox,et al.  Avoidable Cost: Ride a Double Auction Roller Coaster , 1996 .

[30]  H. Outhred,et al.  Forward contracts for the operation of an electricity industry under spot pricing , 1990 .

[31]  Stephen J. Rassenti,et al.  Designing `smart' computer-assisted markets : An experimental auction for gas networks , 1989 .

[32]  S. Rassenti,et al.  Discriminatory Price Auctions in Electricity Markets: Low Volatility at the Expense of High Price Levels , 2003 .