“Illusion of control" in Time-Horizon Minority and Parrondo Games

Human beings like to believe they are in control of their destiny. This ubiquitous trait seems to increase motivation and persistence, and is probably evolutionarily adaptive [J.D. Taylor, S.E. Brown, Psych. Bull. 103, 193 (1988); A. Bandura, Self-efficacy: the exercise of control (WH Freeman, New York, 1997)]. But how good really is our ability to control? How successful is our track record in these areas? There is little understanding of when and under what circumstances we may over-estimate [E. Langer, J. Pers. Soc. Psych. 7, 185 (1975)] or even lose our ability to control and optimize outcomes, especially when they are the result of aggregations of individual optimization processes. Here, we demonstrate analytically using the theory of Markov Chains and by numerical simulations in two classes of games, the Time-Horizon Minority Game [M.L. Hart, P. Jefferies, N.F. Johnson, Phys. A 311, 275 (2002)] and the Parrondo Game [J.M.R. Parrondo, G.P. Harmer, D. Abbott, Phys. Rev. Lett. 85, 5226 (2000); J.M.R. Parrondo, How to cheat a bad mathematician (ISI, Italy, 1996)], that agents who optimize their strategy based on past information may actually perform worse than non-optimizing agents. In other words, low-entropy (more informative) strategies under-perform high-entropy (or random) strategies. This provides a precise definition of the “illusion of control” in certain set-ups a priori defined to emphasize the importance of optimization. Copyright EDP Sciences/Societa Italiana di Fisica/Springer-Verlag 2007

[1]  Abbott,et al.  New paradoxical games based on brownian ratchets , 2000, Physical review letters.

[2]  Erkki Oja,et al.  Artificial neural networks. Formal models and their applications , 2005 .

[3]  J.Menche,et al.  It is worth thinking twice or Improving the performance of minority games , 2003 .

[4]  Stephen P. Berczuk,et al.  Software Configuration Management Patterns: Effective Teamwork, Practical Integration , 2003 .

[5]  Xia Li,et al.  Calibration of Cellular Automata by Using Neural Networks for the Simulation of Complex Urban Systems , 2001 .

[6]  Erkki Oja,et al.  Artificial Neural Networks: Formal Models and Their Applications - ICANN 2005, 15th International Conference, Warsaw, Poland, September 11-15, 2005, Proceedings, Part II , 2005, International Conference on Artificial Neural Networks.

[7]  W. Arthur Out-of-equilibrium economics and agent-based modeling , 2006 .

[8]  K. Kaski,et al.  Intelligent minority game with genetic crossover strategies , 2002, cond-mat/0209525.

[9]  David Kinderlehrer,et al.  Diffusion-Mediated Transport¶and the Flashing Ratchet , 2002 .

[10]  Zecchina,et al.  Statistical mechanics of systems with heterogeneous agents: minority games , 1999, Physical review letters.

[11]  A. Bandura Self-Efficacy: The Exercise of Control , 1997, Journal of Cognitive Psychotherapy.

[12]  Searching good strategies in evolutionary minority game using variable length genetic algorithm , 2004 .

[13]  Incorporating inertia into multiagent systems. , 2006 .

[14]  John Duffy,et al.  Learning, information, and sorting in market entry games: theory and evidence , 2005, Games Econ. Behav..

[15]  T. Grandin,et al.  Animals in translation : using the mysteries of autism to decode animal behavior , 2005 .

[16]  Sergei Maslov,et al.  Optimal Investment Strategy for Risky Assets , 1998 .

[17]  Luís C. Lamb,et al.  Towards understanding the role of learning models in the dynamics of the minority game , 2004, 16th IEEE International Conference on Tools with Artificial Intelligence.

[18]  R. Pyke,et al.  On random walks and diffusions related to Parrondo's games , 2003 .

[19]  James S. Doran,et al.  What Really Matters When Buying and Selling Stocks , 2007 .

[20]  L. Dinis,et al.  Optimal strategies in collective Parrondo games , 2002, cond-mat/0212358.

[21]  Derek Abbott,et al.  Parrondo's paradox , 1999 .

[22]  U. Michigan,et al.  Evolution in minority games. (II). Games with variable strategy spaces , 1999, adap-org/9906001.

[23]  Shelley E. Taylor,et al.  Illusion and well-being: a social psychological perspective on mental health. , 1988, Psychological bulletin.

[24]  Marko Sysi-Aho,et al.  Searching for good strategies in adaptive minority games. , 2004, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[25]  Prost,et al.  Asymmetric pumping of particles. , 1994, Physical review letters.

[26]  M. Sutter,et al.  Is more information always better?: Experimental financial markets with cumulative information , 2008 .

[27]  Catherine Johnson,et al.  Animals in Translation , 2005 .

[28]  Yi-Cheng Zhang,et al.  Emergence of cooperation and organization in an evolutionary game , 1997 .

[29]  Derek Abbott,et al.  Brownian ratchets and Parrondo's games. , 2001, Chaos.

[30]  Matteo Marsili,et al.  Modeling market mechanism with minority game , 1999, cond-mat/9909265.

[31]  P. M. Hui,et al.  Crowd-anticrowd theory of multi-agent market games , 2001 .

[32]  Neil F Johnson,et al.  Winning combinations of history-dependent games. , 2003, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[33]  Yicheng Zhang,et al.  On the minority game: Analytical and numerical studies , 1998, cond-mat/9805084.

[34]  H. Moraal LETTER TO THE EDITOR: Counterintuitive behaviour in games based on spin models , 2000 .

[35]  Magnus Boman,et al.  Parrondo Strategies for Artificial Traders , 2001, ArXiv.

[36]  G. J. Rodgers,et al.  The Hamming Distance in the Minority Game , 1999, adap-org/9902001.

[37]  M Andrecut,et al.  Q learning in the minority game. , 2001, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[38]  Michael L. Hart,et al.  Dynamics of the time horizon minority game , 2002 .