Slutsky matrix norms: The size, classification, and comparative statics of bounded rationality

Abstract Given any observed demand behavior —by means of a demand function—, we quantify by how much it departs from rationality. The measure of the gap is the smallest Frobenius norm of the correcting matrix function that would yield a Slutsky matrix with its standard rationality properties (symmetry, singularity, and negative semidefiniteness). As a result, we are able to suggest a useful classification of departures from rationality, corresponding to three anomalies: inattentiveness to changes in purchasing power, money illusion, and violations of the compensated law of demand. Errors in comparative-statics predictions from assuming rationality are decomposed as the sum of a behavioral error (due to the agent) and a specification error (due to the modeller). Illustrations are provided using several bounded rationality models.

[1]  Martin Browning,et al.  Best Nonparametric Bounds on Demand Responses , 2005 .

[2]  H. Varian Non-parametric Tests of Consumer Behaviour , 1983 .

[3]  Geoffroy de Clippel,et al.  Bounded Rationality and Limited Datasets: Testable Implications, Identifiability, and Out-of-Sample Prediction , 2012 .

[4]  Reinhard John A first order characterization of generalized monotonicity , 2000, Math. Program..

[5]  Berthold R. Haag,et al.  Testing and imposing Slutsky symmetry in nonparametric demand systems , 2009 .

[6]  D. Jerison,et al.  Real income growth and revealed preference inconsistency , 2001 .

[7]  L. J. Savage,et al.  The Foundations of Statistics , 1955 .

[8]  Victor H. Aguiar,et al.  Slutsky Matrix Norms and the Size of Bounded Rationality , 2014 .

[9]  J. Myjak,et al.  On continuous approximations for multifunctions , 1986 .

[10]  SangMok Lee,et al.  The Money Pump as a Measure of Revealed Preference Violations , 2011, Journal of Political Economy.

[11]  Frits C. R. Spieksma,et al.  Goodness-of-Fit Measures for Revealed Preference Tests: Complexity Results and Algorithms , 2014, TEAC.

[12]  Xavier Gabaix,et al.  A Sparsity-Based Model of Bounded Rationality , 2011 .

[13]  Andreu Mas-Colell,et al.  The Demand Theory of the Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference , 1976 .

[14]  Syngjoo Choi,et al.  Estimating Ambiguity Aversion in a Portfolio Choice Experiment , 2009 .

[15]  G. Pedersen,et al.  Diagonalizing matrices over C(X) , 1984 .

[16]  Hal R. Varian,et al.  GOODNESS-OF-FIT IN OPTIMIZING MODELS , 1989 .

[17]  Lawrence M. Graves The Theory of Functions of Real Variables , 2009 .

[18]  Rosa L. Matzkin,et al.  Testing strictly concave rationality , 1991 .

[19]  Revealed preference cycles and the slutsky matrix , 1977 .

[20]  T. Russell How quasi-rational are you?: A behavioral interpretation of a two form which measures non-integrability of a system of demand equations , 1997 .

[21]  A. Mas-Colell Continuous and smooth consumers: Approximation theorems , 1974 .

[22]  A. Rubinstein,et al.  Rationalizing choice functions by multiple rationales , 2002 .

[23]  Kam-Chau Wong,et al.  Revealed preference and differentiable demand , 2005 .

[24]  D. Azagra,et al.  Uniform approximation of continuous mappings by smooth mappings with no critical points on Hilbert manifolds , 2002, math/0203237.

[25]  R. Schnabel,et al.  Least Change Secant Updates for Quasi-Newton Methods , 1978 .

[26]  Jean-Charles Rochet,et al.  Revealed Preferences and Differentiable Demand: Notes and Comments , 1987 .

[27]  A. Shleifer,et al.  Salience and Consumer Choice , 2012, Journal of Political Economy.

[28]  H. Houthakker Revealed Preference and the Utility Function , 1950 .

[29]  Marcel K. Richter,et al.  Nontransitive-nontotal consumer theory , 1986 .

[30]  B. Kőszegi,et al.  A Model of Focusing in Economic Choice , 2011 .

[31]  Xiaohong Chen Chapter 76 Large Sample Sieve Estimation of Semi-Nonparametric Models , 2007 .

[32]  James J. Heckman,et al.  Estimating the Technology of Cognitive and Noncognitive Skill Formation. NBER Working Paper No. 15664. , 2010 .

[33]  Rosa L. Matzkin,et al.  Bounding quantile demand functions using revealed preference inequalities , 2011 .

[34]  J. Quah Weak axiomatic demand theory , 2006 .

[35]  Susanne M. Schennach,et al.  Recent Advances in the Measurement Error Literature , 2016 .

[36]  Efe A. Ok,et al.  A Unified Approach to Revealed Preference Theory: The Case of Rational Choice , 2013 .

[37]  Yoram Halevy,et al.  Parametric Recoverability of Preferences , 2018, Journal of Political Economy.

[38]  Hal R. Varian,et al.  Non-parametric analysis of optimizing behavior with measurement error , 1985 .

[39]  Sergey V. Malakhov Equazione di Slutsky “nelle loro mani”: il centenario “Sulla teoria del bilancio del consumatore” , 2014 .

[40]  R. Anderson “Almost” implies “near” , 1986 .

[41]  Richard H. Thaler,et al.  Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice , 1985, Mark. Sci..

[42]  David Jerison,et al.  Approximately rational consumer demand and ville cycles , 1992 .

[43]  Miguel A. Ballester,et al.  A Measure of Rationality and Welfare , 2015, Journal of Political Economy.

[44]  M. Richter Revealed Preference Theory , 1966 .

[45]  Jan Heufer,et al.  Consistent subsets: Computationally feasible methods to compute the Houtman–Maks-index , 2015 .

[46]  Birgit Grodal,et al.  A note on the space of preference relations , 1974 .

[47]  Jan Heufer,et al.  Consistent Subsets – Computationally Feasible Methods to Compute the Houtman-Maks-Index , 2014 .

[48]  D. Jerison,et al.  A discrete characterization of Slutsky symmetry , 1996 .

[49]  L. Hurwicz,et al.  VILLE AXIOMS AND CONSUMER THEORY , 1979 .

[50]  M. Dean,et al.  Is it All Connected? A Testing Ground for Unified Theories of Behavioral Economics Phenomena , 2015 .

[51]  N. Higham COMPUTING A NEAREST SYMMETRIC POSITIVE SEMIDEFINITE MATRIX , 1988 .

[52]  Wing Hung Wong,et al.  On constrained multivariate splines and their approximations , 1984 .

[53]  Akitoshi Kawamura,et al.  Computational Complexity of Smooth Differential Equations , 2012, MFCS.

[54]  Kenneth J. Arrow,et al.  Preference, production, and capital: On the integrability of demand functions , 1989 .

[55]  Akitoshi Kawamura,et al.  Computational Complexity of Smooth Differential Equations , 2012, MFCS.

[56]  Stefan Hoderlein How many consumers are rational , 2009 .

[57]  Tong Li,et al.  Robust and consistent estimation of nonlinear errors-in-variables models , 2002 .

[58]  Martin Browning,et al.  Efficient Intra-Household Allocations: A General Characterization and Empirical Tests , 1998 .

[59]  S. N. Afriat,et al.  On a system of inequalities in demand analysis , 1973 .

[60]  Justine S. Hastings,et al.  FUNGIBILITY AND CONSUMER CHOICE: EVIDENCE FROM COMMODITY PRICE SHOCKS. , 2013, The quarterly journal of economics.

[61]  F. Lachmann How Many Selves Make a Person , 1996 .

[62]  R. John The weak axiom of revealed preference and homogeneity of demand functions , 1995 .

[63]  M. Dean,et al.  Measuring Rationality with the Minimum Cost of Revealed Preference Violations , 2014, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[64]  Holger Dette,et al.  Testing Multivariate Economic Restrictions Using Quantiles: The Example of Slutsky Negative Semidefiniteness , 2011 .

[65]  N. Higham MATRIX NEARNESS PROBLEMS AND APPLICATIONS , 1989 .

[66]  X. Gabaix,et al.  Optimal Taxation with Behavioral Agents , 2015, American Economic Review.

[67]  Victor H. Aguiar,et al.  Classifying bounded rationality in limited data sets: a Slutsky matrix approach , 2018, SERIEs.

[68]  Alan L. Yuille,et al.  The Concave-Convex Procedure , 2003, Neural Computation.

[69]  D. Jerison,et al.  Approximately rational consumer demand , 1993 .

[70]  H. Guggenheimer A simple proof of Frobenius’s integration theorem , 1962 .

[71]  W. Newey,et al.  The asymptotic variance of semiparametric estimators , 1994 .