Designing supply contracts in supplier vs buyer-driven channels: The impact of leadership, contract flexibility and information asymmetry

In the context of supply contract design, the more powerful party usually has the ability to assume the leadership position. Traditionally, the supplier (e.g., manufacturer) has been more powerful, and, hence, the existing literature in the area emphasizes supplier-driven contracts. However, in some current markets, such as the B2B grocery channel, the power has shifted to the buyer (e.g., retailer). In keeping with these trends, this paper considers a buyer-driven channel and two specific cases are analyzed where the buyer has: (i) full information; and (ii) incomplete information about the supplier's cost structure under three general contract types. The buyer's optimal contracts and profits for all of the corresponding six scenarios are derived. A comparison of the presented results with previous work on supplier-driven channels allows an analysis of the individual and joint impacts of leadership structure, contract flexibility and information asymmetry on supply chain performance. It is shown that, from the system's perspective, the buyer-driven channel is more efficient than the supplier-driven channel under an optimal one-part linear contract. The common wisdom is confirmed that assuming the leadership position is beneficial for the leader in both supplier and buyer-driven channels and the value of the leadership in either channel is greater under more general contract types under full information. Further, under conditions of information asymmetry, it is demonstrated that the leadership is not necessarily beneficial for either party, and, hence, the common wisdom is not valid. Interestingly, it is found that sometimes one party can forfeit the leadership and still achieve a higher profit. [Supplementary materials are available for this article. Go to the publisher's online edition of IIE Transactions for the following free supplemental resource: Appendix]

[1]  R. Vidal Dynamic optimization: The calculus of variations and optimal control in economics and management: Morton I. KAMIEN and Nancy L. SCHWARTZ Volume 4 in: Dynamic Economics: Theory and Applications, North-Holland, New York, 1981, xi + 331 pages, Dfl.90.00 , 1982 .

[2]  George Hendrikse,et al.  The Theory of Industrial Organization , 1989 .

[3]  S. C. Choi,et al.  Price Competition in a Channel Structure with a Common Retailer , 1991 .

[4]  M. Petit Dynamic optimization. The calculus of variations and optimal control in economics and management : by Morton I. Kamien and Nancy L. Schwartz. Second Edition. North-Holland (Advanced Textbooks in Economics), Amsterdam and New York, 1991. Pp. xvii+377. ISBN0-444- 01609-0 , 1994 .

[5]  Paul R. Messinger,et al.  Has Power Shifted in the Grocery Channel , 1995 .

[6]  S. Nahmias,et al.  Modeling Supply Chain Contracts: A Review , 1999 .

[7]  C. Corbett,et al.  A Supplier's Optimal Quantity Discount Policy Under Asymmetric Information , 2000 .

[8]  Marshall L. Fisher,et al.  Supply Chain Inventory Management and the Value of Shared Information , 2000 .

[9]  Albert Y. Ha Supplier‐buyer contracting: Asymmetric cost information and cutoff level policy for buyer participation , 2001 .

[10]  Gérard P. Cachon,et al.  Contracting to Assure Supply: How to Share Demand Forecasts in a Supply Chain , 2001, Manag. Sci..

[11]  Marketing fees reflect relationship between suppliers and supermarkets , 2001 .

[12]  P. Griffin,et al.  Supplier- and buyer-driven channels in a two-stage supply chain , 2002 .

[13]  William L. Wilkie,et al.  Marketing Research and Public Policy: The Case of Slotting Fees , 2002 .

[14]  Gérard P. Cachon Supply Chain Coordination with Contracts , 2003, Supply Chain Management.

[15]  Yigal Gerchak,et al.  Capacity Games in Assembly Systems with Uncertain Demand , 2003, Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag..

[16]  Gérard P. Cachon The Allocation of Inventory Risk in a Supply Chain: Push, Pull, and Advance - Purchase Discount Contracts , 2004, Manag. Sci..

[17]  Kusum L. Ailawadi,et al.  An Empirical Analysis of the Determinants of Retail Margins: The Role of Store-Brand Share , 2004 .

[18]  Christopher S. Tang,et al.  Designing Supply Contracts: Contract Type and Information Asymmetry , 2004, Manag. Sci..

[19]  Hon-Shiang Lau,et al.  Some two-echelon supply-chain games: Improving from deterministic-symmetric-information to stochastic-asymmetric-information models , 2005, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[20]  Fuqiang Zhang,et al.  Procuring Fast Delivery: Sole Sourcing with Information Asymmetry , 2006, Manag. Sci..

[21]  Eric Sucky,et al.  Production , Manufacturing and Logistics A bargaining model with asymmetric information for a single supplier – single buyer problem , 2005 .

[22]  Brian S. Fugate,et al.  SUPPLY CHAIN MANAGEMENT COORDINATION MECHANISMS , 2006 .

[23]  Benjamin Klein,et al.  The Economics of Slotting Contracts , 2007, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[24]  Hon-Shiang Lau,et al.  Pricing and volume discounting for a dominant retailer with uncertain manufacturing cost information , 2007, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[25]  Hon-Shiang Lau,et al.  A stochastic and asymmetric-information framework for a dominant-manufacturer supply chain , 2007, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[26]  M. Erkoc,et al.  Supply contracts in manufacturer‐retailer interactions with manufacturer‐quality and retailer effort‐induced demand , 2008 .

[27]  Hon-Shiang Lau,et al.  How a dominant retailer might design a purchase contract for a newsvendor-type product with price-sensitive demand , 2008, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[28]  Mahesh Nagarajan,et al.  Game-Theoretic Analysis of Cooperation Among Supply Chain Agents: Review and Extensions , 2008, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[29]  F. Arcelus,et al.  Pricing and rebate policies in the two-echelon supply chain with asymmetric information under price-dependent, stochastic demand , 2008 .

[30]  Yunzeng Wang,et al.  Revenue‐Sharing vs. Wholesale‐Price Contracts in Assembly Systems with Random Demand , 2004 .