VERTICAL DIFFERENTIATION, PERCEPTIONS RESTRUCTURING, AND WINE CHOICES: THE CASE OF THE GRAN SELEZIONE IN CHIANTI WINES

We conduct a choice experiment where the number of labels vertically differentiating Chianti wines (Chianti, Chianti Classico, Chianti Classico Riserva, Chianti Classico Gran Selezione) is augmented incrementally in a between-subject design, eliciting both quality perceptions and wine choices. We find that quality expectations are endogenous to the labeling regime, and adding a high-quality label (e.g., Chianti Gran Selezione) decreases the perceived quality of all other Chianti wines (comparative stigma). A model conditioning on subjective quality perceptions with heterogeneous WTP for quality is then proposed, and estimated via random parameter multinomial logit. The endogeneity problem arising from using subjective beliefs as regressors is addressed by means of a control-function approach. Results are compared to reduced form approaches where the marginal utility of quality and subjective perceptions are confounded in a single label-specific estimate, and the model is used to determine how much of the cannibalization observed after introducing higher-tier quality standards is attributable to restructuring of perceptions and comparative stigma.

[1]  David Kjellberg Measuring Expectations , 1999, Identification Problems in the Social Sciences.

[2]  K. Train,et al.  Forecasting new product penetration with flexible substitution patterns , 1998 .

[3]  Marvin T. Batte,et al.  Consumer preferences for local production and other value-added label claims for a processed food product , 2012 .

[4]  B. Roe,et al.  Consumer willingness-to-pay to reduce the probability of retail foodborne pathogen contamination. , 2010 .

[5]  Alf Zimmer,et al.  Verbal Vs. Numerical Processing of Subjective Probabilities , 1983 .

[6]  L. Menapace,et al.  Quality certification by geographical indications, trademarks and firm reputation , 2012 .

[7]  S. Rosen,et al.  Monopoly and product quality , 1978 .

[8]  J. Habbema,et al.  Labeled versus unlabeled discrete choice experiments in health economics: an application to colorectal cancer screening. , 2010, Value in health : the journal of the International Society for Pharmacoeconomics and Outcomes Research.

[9]  E. Brunswik Perception and the Representative Design of Psychological Experiments , 1957 .

[10]  J. C. Naylor,et al.  Characteristics of the human inference process in complex choice behavior situations , 1966 .

[11]  M. Wedel,et al.  The No—Choice Alternative in Conjoint Choice Experiments , 2001 .

[12]  J. Lusk,et al.  Cognitive Biases in the Assimilation of Scientific Information on Global Warming and Genetically Modified Food , 2015 .

[13]  S. Kroll,et al.  Food Beliefs: Elicitation, Estimation and Implications for Labeling Policy , 2015 .

[14]  J. Lusk,et al.  The signaling effect of mandatory labels on genetically engineered food , 2014 .

[15]  D. McFadden,et al.  MIXED MNL MODELS FOR DISCRETE RESPONSE , 2000 .

[16]  A. Hole Fitting Mixed Logit Models by Using Maximum Simulated Likelihood , 2007 .

[17]  basit. zafar Can Subjective Expectations Data be Used in Choice Models? Evidence on Cognitive Biases , 2010 .

[18]  Anette Boom,et al.  Asymmetric International Minimum Quality Standards and Vertical Differentiation , 1995 .

[19]  Timothy B. Heath,et al.  The Asymmetric Effects of Extending Brands to Lower and Higher Quality , 2011 .

[20]  Wuyang Hu,et al.  Substitutes or Complements? Consumer Preference for Local and Organic Food Attributes , 2015 .

[21]  T. Schroeder,et al.  Distinguishing beliefs from preferences in food choice , 2014 .

[22]  Travis J. Lybbert,et al.  Consumer knowledge affects valuation of product attributes: Experimental results for wine , 2016 .

[23]  K. Grunert Food quality and safety: consumer perception and demand , 2005 .

[24]  A. Yiannaka,et al.  Market and Welfare Effects of Second‐Generation, Consumer‐Oriented GM Products , 2008 .

[25]  Pradeep K. Chintagunta,et al.  Product line extensions and competitive market interactions: An empirical analysis , 1998 .

[26]  R. Mittelhammer,et al.  Segmenting the Wine Market Based on Price: Hedonic Regression when Different Prices mean Different Products , 2007 .

[27]  H. Kaiser,et al.  Does Production Labeling Stigmatize Conventional Milk? , 2009 .

[28]  Pradeep K. Chintagunta,et al.  Investigating the effects of a line extension or new brand introduction on market structure , 1996 .

[29]  M. Darby,et al.  Free Competition and the Optimal Amount of Fraud , 1973, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[30]  Marcus Cunha,et al.  Harmful Upward Line Extensions: Can the Launch of Premium Products Result in Competitive Disadvantages? , 2015 .

[31]  Adeline Delavande,et al.  Pill, Patch, or Shot? Subjective Expectations and Birth Control Choice , 2005 .

[32]  Hayne E. Leland,et al.  Quacks, Lemons, and Licensing: A Theory of Minimum Quality Standards , 1979, Journal of Political Economy.

[33]  J. McCluskey,et al.  Reputation Leaders, Quality Laggards: Incentive Structure in Markets with Both Private and Collective Reputations , 2012 .

[34]  K. Train,et al.  A Control Function Approach to Endogeneity in Consumer Choice Models , 2010 .

[35]  N. Bockstael,et al.  The Welfare Implications of Minimum Quality Standards , 1984 .

[36]  J. McCluskey,et al.  The Economics of Nested Names: Name Specificity, Reputations, and Price Premia , 2010 .

[37]  P. Nelson Information and Consumer Behavior , 1970, Journal of Political Economy.

[38]  D. McFadden Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior , 1972 .