A Consumption-Based Explanation of the Cross Section of Expected Stock Returns

When utility is non-separable in nondurable and durable consumption, optimal portfolio allocation implies a two-factor model in nondurable and durable consumption growth. The model nests the Consumption CAPM as a special case, where the risk price for durable consumption is restricted to zero. I test the model on 25 Fama-French portfolios sorted by size and book-to-market equity. I find that small stocks and value stocks have higher durable consumption betas than large stocks and growth stocks, explaining their high average returns. The consumption-based model model explains the variation in average returns across the 25 portfolios better than the Fama-French three-factor model. JEL classification: E21, G12. First draft: March 7, 2003. ∗Department of Economics, Harvard University. E-mail: yogo@fas.harvard.edu. I thank John Campbell, Borja Larrain, and participants of the Harvard econometrics lunch for helpful comments.

[1]  M. Shapiro,et al.  Risk and Return: Consumption Versus Market Beta , 1984 .

[2]  E. Fama,et al.  The Cross‐Section of Expected Stock Returns , 1992 .

[3]  W. Newey,et al.  A Simple, Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelationconsistent Covariance Matrix , 1986 .

[4]  R. Gibbons,et al.  Empirical Tests of the Consumption-Oriented CAPM , 1989 .

[5]  W. Sharpe CAPITAL ASSET PRICES: A THEORY OF MARKET EQUILIBRIUM UNDER CONDITIONS OF RISK* , 1964 .

[6]  W. Newey,et al.  Large sample estimation and hypothesis testing , 1986 .

[7]  R. Mehra,et al.  THE EQUITY PREMIUM A Puzzle , 1985 .

[8]  Douglas T. Breeden,et al.  Prices of State-Contingent Claims Implicit in Option Prices , 1978 .

[9]  W. D. Haan Evaluation and Combination of Conditional Quantile Forecasts , 2000 .

[10]  G. Constantinides,et al.  Habit Persistence and Durability in Aggregate Consumption: Empirical Tests , 1991 .

[11]  D. Andrews Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation , 1991 .

[12]  L. Hansen Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators , 1982 .

[13]  M. Lettau,et al.  Resurrecting the (C)Capm: A Cross-Sectional Test When Risk Premia Wre Time-Varying , 1999 .

[14]  Stijn van Nieuwerburgh,et al.  Housing Collateral, Consumption Insurance and Risk Premia , 2002 .

[15]  Masao Ogaki,et al.  Measuring Intertemporal Substitution: The Role of Durable Goods , 1998, Journal of Political Economy.

[16]  John Y. Campbell,et al.  Consumption-Based Asset Pricing , 2002 .

[17]  James D. Hamilton Time Series Analysis , 1994 .

[18]  Mark Rubinstein,et al.  The Valuation of Uncertain Income Streams and the Pricing of Options , 1976 .

[19]  J. Lintner SECURITY PRICES, RISK, AND MAXIMAL GAINS FROM DIVERSIFICATION , 1965 .

[20]  E. Fama,et al.  Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds , 1993 .

[21]  E. J. Hannan,et al.  Multiple time series , 1970 .

[22]  Andrew T. Levin,et al.  A Practitioner's Guide to Robust Covariance Matrix Estimation , 1996 .

[23]  J. Campbell,et al.  By Force of Habit: A Consumption‐Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.

[24]  Douglas T. Breeden An Intertemporal Asset Pricing Model with Stochastic Consumption and Investment Opportunities , 1979 .

[25]  Kenneth J. Singleton,et al.  Modeling the term structure of interest rates under non-separable utility and durability of goods , 1986 .

[26]  W. Newey,et al.  Uniform Convergence in Probability and Stochastic Equicontinuity , 1991 .

[27]  J. Wooldridge Estimation and inference for dependent processes , 1994 .