Tying, Foreclosure, and Exclusion

Tied sales have a long history of scrutiny under the antitrust laws of the United States. The primary basis for the condemnation of this practice has been the court's belief in what has come to be known as the "leverage theory" of tying: that is, that tying provides a mechanism whereby a firm with monopoly power in one market can use the leverage provided by this power to foreclose sales in, and thereby monopolize, a second market. In recent years, however, the leverage theory has come under heavy attack. In this paper, I reconsider the leverage hypothesis. I argue that, in an important sense, the models used by the critics of the leverage theory which all assume that the tied good market has a competitive, constant returns-to-scale structure- are incapable of addressing the central concern of the leverage theory, that tying can be profitably used to change the market structure of the tied good market. I then demonstrate that when the tied good market has an oligopolistic structure, tying can indeed serve as a mechanism for leveraging market power through the foreclosure of tied market rivals sales. The mechanism through which this foreclosure occurs, its profitability for the monopolist, and its welfare implications are discussed in detail.

[1]  Edward Hirsch Levi,et al.  Law and the Future: Trade Regulation , 1956 .

[2]  Bowman,et al.  Tying Arrangements and the Leverage Problem , 1957 .

[3]  R. Selten Reexamination of the perfectness concept for equilibrium points in extensive games , 1975, Classics in Game Theory.

[4]  M. Spence Product Selection, Fixed Costs, and Monopolistic Competition , 1976 .

[5]  Janet L. Yellen,et al.  Commodity Bundling and the Burden of Monopoly , 1976 .

[6]  Richard A. Posner,et al.  Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective , 1977 .

[7]  Roger D. Blair,et al.  Vertical integration, tying, and antitrust policy , 1978 .

[8]  S. Salop Monopolistic competition with outside goods , 1979 .

[9]  Frederick R. Warren-Boulton,et al.  Vertical control of markets : business and labor practices , 1979 .

[10]  E. Warhit The economics of tie-in sales , 1980 .

[11]  R. Schmalensee Antitrust and the New Industrial Economics , 1982 .

[12]  Richard Schmalensee,et al.  Commodity Bundling by Single-Product Monopolies , 1982, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[13]  A. Shaked,et al.  Relaxing price competition through product differentiation , 1982 .

[14]  Book Review: Folded, Spindled, and Mutilated: Economic Analysis and U.S. v. IBM , 1983, The Antitrust Bulletin.

[15]  David M. Kreps,et al.  Quantity Precommitment and Bertrand Competition Yield Cournot Outcomes , 1983 .

[16]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  The Fat-Cat Effect, the Puppy-Dog Ploy, and the Lean and Hungry Look , 1984 .

[17]  J. Benoît Financially Constrained Entry in a Game with Incomplete Information , 1984 .

[18]  J. Geanakoplos,et al.  Multimarket Oligopoly: Strategic Substitutes and Complements , 1985, Journal of Political Economy.

[19]  L. Kaplow Extension of Monopoly Power through Leverage , 1985 .

[20]  Antitrust and regulation: Essays in memory of John J. McGowan : edited and introduced by Franklin M. Fisher (The MIT Press, Cambridge, 1985) 310 pages , 1986 .

[21]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  A "Signal-Jamming" Theory of Predation , 1986 .

[22]  J. Geanakoplos,et al.  Free Entry and Social Inefficiency , 1986 .

[23]  S. Salop,et al.  Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs To Achieve Power over Price , 1986 .

[24]  J. Tirole The Theory of Industrial Organization , 1988 .

[25]  Garth Saloner,et al.  Predation, Monopolization and Antitrust , 1989 .

[26]  M. Whinston,et al.  Multiproduct Monopoly, Commodity Bundling, and Correlation of Values , 1989 .

[27]  David de Meza,et al.  A strategic motivation for commodity bundling , 1990 .