The Arbitrator as Agent: Why Deferential Review is Not Always Pro-Arbitration

It has long been thought that minimal judicial review of arbitral awards helps further the federal policy of supporting arbitration. This contribution to a symposium on Judge Easterbrook’s judicial contributions argues that this position has its limits. Viewing the arbitrator as an agent of the parties, as Judge Easterbrook does in the 2001 case of George Watts and Sons v. Tiffany, helps to illuminate that parties might sometimes want to choose a higher level of judicial review than the minimal level required by the Federal Arbitration Act. Allowing parties to opt into higher levels of review might allow high-quality arbitrators to trade on their skill, ensuring that the pool of arbitrators as a whole is of higher quality. The U.S. Supreme Court’s 2008 decision in Hall Street Associates v. Mattel, however, holds that parties cannot contract for higher levels of review of arbitral awards. Hall Street, perversely, might reduce the overall quality of arbitration, leading to more contract disputes in the federal courts.

[1]  Richard A. Posner,et al.  Inferring the Winning Party in the Supreme Court from the Pattern of Questioning at Oral Argument , 2010, The Journal of Legal Studies.

[2]  Saul Levmore Interest Groups and the Problem with Incrementalism , 2009 .

[3]  Randal C. Picker Assessing Competition Issues in the Amended Google Book Search Settlement , 2009 .

[4]  Richard A. Epstein,et al.  Against Permititis: Why Voluntary Organizations Should Regulate the Use of Cancer Drugs , 2009 .

[5]  Richard A. Epstein,et al.  Heller's Gridlock Economy in Perspective: Why There is Too Little, Not Too Much, Private Property , 2009 .

[6]  Richard A. Epstein,et al.  NRA v. City of Chicago: Does the Second Amendment Bind Frank Easterbrook? , 2009 .

[7]  Eric A. Posner,et al.  ProCD v. Zeidenberg and Cognitive Overload in Contractual Bargaining , 2009 .

[8]  Randal C. Picker,et al.  Antitrust and Innovation: Framing Baselines in the Google Book Search Settlement , 2009 .

[9]  Ariel Porat,et al.  Viewing Unconscionability through a Market Lens , 2009 .

[10]  B. Harcourt,et al.  Henry Louis Gates and Racial Profiling: What's the Problem? , 2009 .

[11]  Ramanan Laxminarayan,et al.  Incentives for Surveillance of Infectious Disease Outbreaks , 2009 .

[12]  D. Baird,et al.  The Holmesian Bad Man's First Critic , 2009 .

[13]  D. Baird,et al.  The Bankruptcy Exchange , 2009 .

[14]  Ariel Porat,et al.  Liability for Future Harm , 2009 .

[15]  M. Henderson,et al.  Credit Derivatives Are Not 'Insurance' , 2009 .

[16]  Randal C. Picker,et al.  The Google Book Search Settlement: A New Orphan-Works Monopoly? , 2009 .

[17]  Richard A. Epstein,et al.  The Case Against the Employee Free Choice Act , 2009 .

[18]  B. Harcourt,et al.  Randomization in Criminal Justice: A Criminal Law Conversation , 2009 .

[19]  R. Epstein How to Undermine Tax Increment Financing: The Lessons of Prologis v. City of Chicago , 2009 .

[20]  E. Posner,et al.  The Rights of Migrants , 2009 .

[21]  Luigi Zingales,et al.  The Housing Crisis and Bankruptcy Reform: The Prepackaged Chapter 13 Approach , 2009 .

[22]  L. Strahilevitz The Right to Abandon , 2009 .

[23]  Adam Cox Immigration Law's Organizing Principles , 2009 .

[24]  E. Posner,et al.  Are Judges Overpaid?: A Skeptical Response to the Judicial Salary Debate , 2007 .

[25]  David Weisbach U.S. Energy Tax Policy: Instrument Choice Is Instrument Design , 2010 .

[26]  M. Todd Henderson,et al.  The Nanny Corporation and the Market for Paternalism , 2009 .

[27]  Ariel Porat,et al.  Expanding Liability for Negligence Per Se , 2009 .

[28]  R. Epstein,et al.  Marking to Market: Can Accounting Rules Shake the Foundations of Capitalism? , 2009 .

[29]  S. Hayford Reining in the Manifest Disregard of the Law Standard: The Key to Restoring Order to the Law of Vacatur , 1998 .