Social and strategic imitation: the way to consensus

Humans do not always make rational choices, a fact that experimental economics is putting on solid grounds. The social context plays an important role in determining our actions, and often we imitate friends or acquaintances without any strategic consideration. We explore here the interplay between strategic and social imitative behavior in a coordination problem on a social network. We observe that for interactions on 1D and 2D lattices any amount of social imitation prevents the freezing of the network in domains with different conventions, thus leading to global consensus. For interactions on complex networks, the interplay of social and strategic imitation also drives the system towards global consensus while neither dynamics alone does. We find an optimum value for the combination of imitative behaviors to reach consensus in a minimum time, and two different dynamical regimes to approach it: exponential when social imitation predominates, power-law when strategic considerations prevail.

[1]  Mark S. Granovetter Threshold Models of Collective Behavior , 1978, American Journal of Sociology.

[2]  P. Clifford,et al.  A model for spatial conflict , 1973 .

[3]  M. Nowak Evolutionary Dynamics: Exploring the Equations of Life , 2006 .

[4]  M. Rabin,et al.  Understanding Social Preference with Simple Tests , 2001 .

[5]  Herbert Gintis,et al.  The hitchhiker's guide to altruism: gene-culture coevolution, and the internalization of norms. , 2003, Journal of theoretical biology.

[6]  Ángel Sánchez,et al.  Evolutionary game theory: Temporal and spatial effects beyond replicator dynamics , 2009, Physics of life reviews.

[7]  Daniele Vilone,et al.  Solution of voter model dynamics on annealed small-world networks. , 2004, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[8]  F. Vazquez,et al.  Analytical solution of the voter model on uncorrelated networks , 2008, 0803.1686.

[9]  R. Cooper,et al.  Coordination Games: Technological Complementarities , 1999 .

[10]  Claudio Castellano,et al.  Incomplete ordering of the voter model on small-world networks , 2003 .

[11]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Evolution of public cooperation on interdependent networks: The impact of biased utility functions , 2012, ArXiv.

[12]  Ángel Sánchez,et al.  Imperfect imitation can enhance cooperation , 2009, ArXiv.

[13]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Exploration dynamics in evolutionary games , 2009, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[14]  E. Fehr,et al.  Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity , 2000, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[15]  Fernando Vega-Redondo,et al.  Evolution, Games, and Economic Behaviour , 1996 .

[16]  V. Eguíluz,et al.  Conservation laws for the voter model in complex networks , 2004, cond-mat/0408101.

[17]  K. Schlag Why Imitate, and If So, How?, : A Boundedly Rational Approach to Multi-armed Bandits , 1998 .

[18]  Krzysztof Suchecki,et al.  Voter model dynamics in complex networks: Role of dimensionality, disorder, and degree distribution. , 2005, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[19]  E. Fehr A Theory of Fairness, Competition and Cooperation , 1998 .

[20]  Alex Arenas,et al.  Topological Traps Control Flow on Real Networks: The Case of Coordination Failures , 2010, PloS one.

[21]  U. Fischbacher,et al.  Why Social Preferences Matter - the Impact of Non-Selfish Motives on Competition, Cooperation and Incentives , 2002 .

[22]  Gary Charness,et al.  Social preferences: Some simple tests and a new model , 2000 .

[23]  R Boyd,et al.  Why people punish defectors. Weak conformist transmission can stabilize costly enforcement of norms in cooperative dilemmas. , 2001, Journal of theoretical biology.

[24]  D. Saad Europhysics Letters , 1997 .

[25]  Bruce A. Reed,et al.  A Critical Point for Random Graphs with a Given Degree Sequence , 1995, Random Struct. Algorithms.

[26]  Floriana Gargiulo,et al.  Influence of Opinion Dynamics on the Evolution of Games , 2012, PloS one.

[27]  Dirk C. Keene Acknowledgements , 1975 .

[28]  Chao Wang,et al.  Imitating emotions instead of strategies in spatial games elevates social welfare , 2011, 1109.1712.

[29]  Krapivsky,et al.  Exact results for kinetics of catalytic reactions. , 1996, Physical review. E, Statistical physics, plasmas, fluids, and related interdisciplinary topics.

[30]  Angel Sánchez,et al.  Altruism may arise from individual selection. , 2004, Journal of theoretical biology.

[31]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary games and spatial chaos , 1992, Nature.

[32]  M. Miguel Social and strategic imitation: the way to , 2012 .

[33]  Raúl Toral,et al.  Global culture: a noise-induced transition in finite systems. , 2003, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[34]  Colin Camerer Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction , 2003 .

[35]  R. Holley,et al.  Ergodic Theorems for Weakly Interacting Infinite Systems and the Voter Model , 1975 .

[36]  Dirk Helbing Interrelations between stochastic equations for systems with pair interactions , 1992 .

[37]  Lawrence E. Blume,et al.  Equilibrium Concepts for Social Interaction Models , 2003, IGTR.

[38]  S. Fortunato,et al.  Statistical physics of social dynamics , 2007, 0710.3256.