Recency, Records, and Recaps

Nash equilibrium takes optimization as a primitive, but suboptimal behavior can persist in simple stochastic decision problems. This has motivated the development of other equilibrium concepts such as cursed equilibrium and behavioral equilibrium. We experimentally study a simple adverse selection (or “lemons”) problem and find that learning models that heavily discount past information (i.e., display recency bias) explain patterns of behavior better than Nash, cursed, or behavioral equilibrium. Providing counterfactual information or a record of past outcomes does little to aid convergence to optimal strategies, but providing sample averages (“recaps”) gets individuals most of the way to optimality. Thus, recency effects are not solely due to limited memory but stem from some other form of cognitive constraints. Our results show the importance of going beyond static optimization and incorporating features of human learning into economic models used in both understanding phenomena and designing market institutions.

[1]  G. A. Miller THE PSYCHOLOGICAL REVIEW THE MAGICAL NUMBER SEVEN, PLUS OR MINUS TWO: SOME LIMITS ON OUR CAPACITY FOR PROCESSING INFORMATION 1 , 1956 .

[2]  Sheryl B. Ball,et al.  An evaluation of learning in the bilateral winner's curse , 1991 .

[3]  A. Tversky,et al.  Naive Strategies in Zero-Sum Games , 1993 .

[4]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  Self-confirming equilibrium , 1993 .

[5]  A. Roth,et al.  Learning in Extensive-Form Games: Experimental Data and Simple Dynamic Models in the Intermediate Term* , 1995 .

[6]  R. Tibshirani Regression Shrinkage and Selection via the Lasso , 1996 .

[7]  Daniel Friedman,et al.  Individual Learning in Normal Form Games: Some Laboratory Results☆☆☆ , 1997 .

[8]  Pierpaolo Battigalli,et al.  Conjectural Equilibria and Rationalizability in a Game with Incomplete Information , 1997 .

[9]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  The Theory of Learning in Games , 1998 .

[10]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  Payoff Information and Self-Confirming Equilibrium , 1999 .

[11]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Experience‐weighted Attraction Learning in Normal Form Games , 1999 .

[12]  R. McKelvey,et al.  An Experimental Study of Jury Decision Rules , 2000, American Political Science Review.

[13]  A. Tversky,et al.  Choices, Values, and Frames , 2000 .

[14]  Eld,et al.  Cursed Equilibrium , 2000 .

[15]  Brit Grosskopf,et al.  Overcoming the Winner's Curse: An Adaptive Learning Perspective , 2002 .

[16]  A. Roth The Economist as Engineer: Game Theory, Experimentation, and Computation as Tools for Design Economics , 2002 .

[17]  Colin Camerer Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction , 2003 .

[18]  Eric J. Johnson,et al.  The Construction of Preference: Do Defaults Save Lives? , 2006 .

[19]  M. Bazerman,et al.  Focusing Failures in Competitive Environments: Explaining Decision Errors in the Monty Hall Game, the Acquiring a Company Problem, and Multiparty Ultimatums , 2003 .

[20]  Eric R. Ziegel,et al.  The Elements of Statistical Learning , 2003, Technometrics.

[21]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  Learning to Play Bayesian Games , 2001, Games Econ. Behav..

[22]  Dan Levin,et al.  The Origin of the Winner's Curse: A Laboratory Study , 2007 .

[23]  Richard S. Sutton,et al.  Reinforcement Learning: An Introduction , 1998, IEEE Trans. Neural Networks.

[24]  George A. Akerlof,et al.  The Market for “Lemons”: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism , 1970 .

[25]  J. Kagel,et al.  Behavioral Equilibrium in Economies with Adverse Selection , 2007 .

[26]  Markku Kaustia,et al.  Do Investors Overweight Personal Experience? Evidence from IPO Subscriptions , 2007 .

[27]  David I. Laibson,et al.  Learning in the Credit Card Market , 2013 .

[28]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Neuroeconomics: decision making and the brain , 2008 .

[29]  Ulrike Malmendier,et al.  Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? , 2009 .

[30]  Josef Hofbauer,et al.  Learning in games with unstable equilibria , 2005, J. Econ. Theory.

[31]  Timothy J. Pleskac,et al.  Decisions from experience: Why small samples? , 2010, Cognition.

[32]  David M. Kreps,et al.  Learning in Extensive Games, I: Self-Confirming Equilibrium , 2010 .

[33]  C. Chabris,et al.  Common (Mis)Beliefs about Memory: A Replication and Comparison of Telephone and Mechanical Turk Survey Methods , 2012, PloS one.

[34]  I. Erev,et al.  On Surprise, Change, and the Effect of Recent Outcomes , 2011, Front. Psychology.

[35]  D. Levine Is Behavioral Economics Doomed? The Ordinary versus the Extraordinary , 2012 .

[36]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  Learning with Recency Bias , 2013 .

[37]  Gary E. Bolton,et al.  Learning and the Economics of Small Decisions , 2013 .

[38]  E. Shafir The Behavioral Foundations of Public Policy , 2013 .

[39]  David G. Rand,et al.  Harnessing Reciprocity to Promote Cooperation and the Provisioning of Public Goods , 2014 .

[40]  David G. Rand,et al.  Social heuristics shape intuitive cooperation , 2014, Nature Communications.

[41]  David G. Rand,et al.  Humans Display a 'Cooperative Phenotype' that is Domain General and Temporally Stable , 2014 .

[42]  David G. Rand,et al.  Promoting cooperation in the field , 2015, Current Opinion in Behavioral Sciences.

[43]  A. Peysakhovich,et al.  When Punishment Doesn't Pay: 'Cold Glow' and Decisions to Punish , 2015 .

[44]  A. Imas The Realization Effect: Risk-Taking after Realized versus Paper Losses , 2016 .

[45]  David G. Rand,et al.  Habits of Virtue: Creating Norms of Cooperation and Defection in the Laboratory , 2015, Manag. Sci..

[46]  Alexander Peysakhovich,et al.  Asymmetric Effects of Favorable and Unfavorable Information on Decision Making Under Ambiguity , 2016, Manag. Sci..