More Evidence on the Distribution of Security Returns

THE SHARPE [18], Lintner [131 and Mossin 1151 capital asset pricing model has provided important insights into such substantive economic issues as capital budgeting, the cost of capital and investment performance. One of the key assumptions in the model is that security returns follow a stable symmetric distribution. The purpose of this paper is to provide additional evidence on the validiity of this assumption. Capital asset pricing models can be derived by assuming that investors are risk adverse and have quadratic utility of wealth functions.' While this assumption is mathematically convenient, it has the unappealing implication that the marginal utility of wealth is negative above some wealth level. Tobin [201 has shown that if asset returns are normally distributed then variance is the proper measure of risk. Thus, the capital asset pricing models are usually based on the assumption that security returns are normally distributed. Serious examination of this assumption began with Fama [5] who analyzed the distribution of the thirty stocks that make up the Dow Jones Industrial Average. His results suggested that security returns are "fat-tailed" or have kurtosis. This evidence casted doubts on the viability of assuming security returns are normally distributed and lead Fama and others to investigate more further the distribution of security returns. There are at least two reasons for this research. First, portfolio theory is sensitive to charges in distributional assumptions. If the distribution of security returns is not stable under addition, it is hard to envision a theory of how to combine securities optimally into portfolios. Second, this research is needed to answer the question of what distribution should be used when testing hypotheses based on security returns. These data have been used to test the efficient market hypothesis, the effect of government regulation and the impact of changes in accounting techniques among other things.2 Thus, both on theoretical and empirical grounds, the question of what distribution security returns follow is important.

[1]  Fischer Black,et al.  The effects of dividend yield and dividend policy on common stock prices and returns , 1974 .

[2]  Andrew H. Chen,et al.  Investigations of Nonstationarity in Prices , 1974 .

[3]  Robert C. Blattberg,et al.  A Comparison of the Stable and Student Distributions as Statistical Models for Stock Prices: Reply , 1974 .

[4]  A. Barnea,et al.  A Reexamination of the Empirical Distribution of Stock Price Changes , 1973 .

[5]  R. Kaplan,et al.  Investor Evaluation of Accounting Information: Some Empirical Evidence , 1972 .

[6]  Myron S. Scholes The Market for Securities: Substitution Versus Price Pressure and the Effects of Information on Share Prices , 1972 .

[7]  R. Officer The Distribution of Stock Returns , 1972 .

[8]  E. Fama,et al.  Parameter Estimates for Symmetric Stable Distributions , 1971 .

[9]  John Teichmoeller A Note on the Distribution of Stock Price Changes , 1971 .

[10]  E. Fama,et al.  Risk, Return, and Equilibrium , 1971, Journal of Political Economy.

[11]  E. Fama,et al.  Some Properties of Symmetric Stable Distributions , 1968 .

[12]  J. Mossin EQUILIBRIUM IN A CAPITAL ASSET MARKET , 1966 .

[13]  B. King Market and Industry Factors in Stock Price Behavior , 1966 .

[14]  J. Lintner THE VALUATION OF RISK ASSETS AND THE SELECTION OF RISKY INVESTMENTS IN STOCK PORTFOLIOS AND CAPITAL BUDGETS , 1965 .

[15]  E. Fama The Behavior of Stock-Market Prices , 1965 .

[16]  W. Sharpe CAPITAL ASSET PRICES: A THEORY OF MARKET EQUILIBRIUM UNDER CONDITIONS OF RISK* , 1964 .

[17]  B. Mandelbrot The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices , 1963 .

[18]  J. Tobin Liquidity Preference as Behavior towards Risk , 1958 .