Goal Setting and Energy Conservation

This paper develops a theoretical model of consumer demand for an energy conservation program that involves non-binding, self-set goals. We present evidence from a Northern Illinois goal-setting program, aimed at reducing residential electricity consumption, that is difficult to reconcile with standard preferences and is broadly consistent with a model of presentbiased consumers with reference-dependent preferences. We find that the need for commitment is correlated with program adoption, higher pre-adoption consumption, and lower responsiveness to goals. Consumers choosing realistic goals persistently save substantially more, achieving savings of nearly 11%, than those choosing very low or unrealistically high goals.

[1]  David I. Laibson,et al.  Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting , 1997 .

[2]  David Huffman,et al.  Reference Points and Effort Provision , 2009, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[3]  Sendhil Mullainathan,et al.  What's Advertising Content Worth? Evidence from a Consumer Credit Marketing Field Experiment , 2009 .

[4]  Paul J. Ferraro,et al.  Are Voters More Likely to Contribute to Other Public Goods? Evidence from a Large‐Scale Randomized Policy Experiment , 2014 .

[5]  Ted O’Donoghue,et al.  Doing It Now or Later , 1999 .

[6]  D. Rapson,et al.  Do Voluntary Carbon Offsets Induce Energy Rebound ? A Conservationist ’ s Dilemma , 2013 .

[7]  R. Pollak,et al.  SECOND-BEST NATIONAL SAVING AND GAME-EQUILIBRIUM GROWTH , 1980 .

[8]  A. Scott,et al.  Fitting Logistic Models Under Case‐Control or Choice Based Sampling , 1986 .

[9]  M. Rabin,et al.  A Model of Reference-Dependent Preferences , 2006 .

[10]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk — Source link , 2007 .

[11]  Matthew Rabin,et al.  Choice and Procrastination , 2000 .

[12]  S. Mullainathan,et al.  Behavior and Energy Policy , 2010, Science.

[13]  Alexander K. Koch,et al.  Self-Regulation Through Goal Setting , 2011, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[14]  Matthew J. Kotchen,et al.  Private Provision of Environmental Public Goods: Household Participation in Green-Electricity Programs , 2007 .

[15]  Devin G. Pope,et al.  Is Tiger Woods Loss Averse? Persistent Bias in the Face of Experience, Competition, and High Stakes , 2009 .

[16]  Jeannet H. Van Houwelingen,et al.  The Effect of Goal-Setting and Daily Electronic Feedback on In-Home Energy Use , 1989 .

[17]  S. Nageeb Ali,et al.  Learning Self-Control , 2011 .

[18]  Matthew Rabin,et al.  Reference-Dependent Consumption Plans , 2009 .

[19]  Matthew E. Kahn,et al.  Energy Conservation "Nudges" and Environmentalist Ideology: Evidence from a Randomized Residential Electricity Field Experiment , 2010 .

[20]  J. Hausman,et al.  Flexible parametric estimation of duration and competing risk models , 1990 .

[21]  Juanjuan Meng,et al.  research platform to scholars worldwide. New York City Cabdrivers ’ Labor Supply Revisited: Reference-Dependent Preferences with Rational-Expectations Targets for Hours and Income , 2008 .

[22]  E. Fehr,et al.  Do Workers Work More If Wages are High? Evidence from a Randomized Field Experiment , 2005 .

[23]  E. A. Locke,et al.  Building a practically useful theory of goal setting and task motivation. A 35-year odyssey. , 2002, The American psychologist.

[24]  Edwin A. Locke,et al.  Relationship of Goal Level to Valence and Instrumentality , 1992 .

[25]  Stephan Meier,et al.  Present-Biased Preferences and Credit Card Borrowing , 2009, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[26]  Michael K. Price,et al.  Using Nonpecuniary Strategies to Influence Behavior: Evidence from a Large-Scale Field Experiment , 2011, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[27]  D. Schanzenbach,et al.  Work Incentives and the Food Stamp Program , 2010 .

[28]  Keith M. Marzilli Ericson,et al.  Expectations as Endowments: Evidence on Reference-Dependent Preferences from Exchange and Valuation Experiments , 2010 .

[29]  Noah J. Goldstein,et al.  Normative Social Influence is Underdetected , 2008, Personality & social psychology bulletin.

[30]  Sarah J. Reber Court-Ordered Desegregation , 2005, The Journal of Human Resources.

[31]  Richard P. Larrick,et al.  Goals as Reference Points , 1999, Cognitive Psychology.

[32]  F. Ohtake,et al.  Hyperbolic discounting, the sign effect, and the body mass index. , 2010, Journal of health economics.

[33]  Charles Sprenger,et al.  An Endowment Effect for Risk: Experimental Tests of Stochastic Reference Points , 2015, Journal of Political Economy.

[34]  Lawrence M. Ausubel,et al.  Time Inconsistency in the Credit Card Market , 2004 .

[35]  R. Pyke,et al.  Logistic disease incidence models and case-control studies , 1979 .

[36]  B. Sianesi An Evaluation of the Swedish System of Active Labor Market Programs in the 1990s , 2004, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[37]  Rich Ling,et al.  Measured energy savings from a more informative energy bill , 1995 .

[38]  David Card,et al.  Family Violence and Football: The Effect of Unexpected Emotional Cues on Violent Behavior , 2009, The quarterly journal of economics.

[39]  H. Allcott,et al.  Social Norms and Energy Conservation , 2011 .

[40]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect theory: analysis of decision under risk , 1979 .

[41]  D. Schanzenbach,et al.  Consumption Responses to In-Kind Transfers: Evidence from the Introduction of the Food Stamp Program , 2007 .

[42]  Steven R. Lerman,et al.  The Estimation of Choice Probabilities from Choice Based Samples , 1977 .

[43]  R. Thaler,et al.  Labor Supply of New York City Cabdrivers: One Day at a Time , 1997 .

[44]  Alice Hsiaw,et al.  Goal-setting and self-control , 2013, J. Econ. Theory.