Using Non‐Governmental Resources to Foster Regulatory Compliance

This article explores means by which non-governmental institutions and resources, both commercial and voluntay, may be enlisted in the interest of regulatory compliance. Following a discussion of non-governmental social control, it reviews the basic institutional forms of indirect governance through which third-party “co-production” of compliance might occur. It then discusses the basic issues which arise when certain public functions are delegated to or devolve upon private interests, and suggests safeguards which might be put in place to enhance the advantages and to minimize the adverse consequences of such devolution. The conclusion seeks to articulate basic principles for the mobilization of third parties in furtherance of compliance, and to encourage the idea of a more participative regulatoy process.

[1]  Paul Starr,et al.  The Meaning of Privatization , 1988 .

[2]  Nancy Reichman,et al.  Ozone Partnerships, the Construction of Regulatory Communities, and the Future of Global Regulatory Power* , 1993 .

[3]  A. Kahn,et al.  Privatization and the Welfare State , 1989 .

[4]  D. Nagin,et al.  Expert Intermediaries and Legal Compliance: The Case of Tax Preparers , 1991, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[5]  R. Gray ACCOUNTING AND ENVIRONMENTALISM: AN EXPLORATION OF THE CHALLENGE OF GENTLY ACCOUNTING FOR... , 1992 .

[6]  Peter Miller,et al.  On the interrelations between accounting and the state , 1990 .

[7]  Coffee,et al.  Understanding the Plaintiff's Attorney: The Implications of Economic Theory for Private Enforcement of Law Through Class and Derivative Actions , 1986 .

[8]  R. Gilson,et al.  Investment Companies as Guardian Shareholders: The Place of the MSIC in the Corporate Governance Debate , 1993 .

[9]  Reinier H. Kraakman Gatekeepers: The Anatomy of a Third-Party Enforcement Strategy , 1986 .

[10]  D. Mceachern ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY IN AUSTRALIA 1981-91: A FORM OF CORPORATISM? , 1993 .

[11]  Anthony King,et al.  Overload: Problems of Governing in the 1970s , 1975 .

[12]  Joel Rogers,et al.  Secondary Associations and Democratic Governance , 1992 .

[13]  Craig B. Little,et al.  Frontiers and Criminal Justice: English Private Prosecution Societies and American Vigilantism in the Eighteenth and Nineteenth Centuries , 1983 .

[14]  Evan H. Caminker The Constitutionality of Qui Tam Actions , 1989 .

[15]  J. Boston Purchasing Policy Advice: The Limits to Contracting Out , 1994 .

[16]  E. Meidinger,et al.  Privatizing Regulatory Enforcement: A Preliminary Assessment of Citizen Suits Under Federal Environmental Laws , 1985 .

[17]  Wolfgang Streeck,et al.  Community, market, state and associations? : the prospective contribution of interest governance to social order , 1985 .

[18]  Gunther Teubner,et al.  Substantive and Reflexive Elements in Modern Law , 2021, Luhmann and Law.

[19]  John Braithwaite,et al.  Enforced Self-Regulation: A New Strategy for Corporate Crime Control , 1982 .

[20]  P. Grabosky Professional Advisers and White Collar Illegality: Towards Explaining and Excusing Professional Failure , 1991 .

[21]  Reinier H. Kraakman Corporate Liability Strategies and the Costs of Legal Controls , 1984 .

[22]  L. Hartz Economic policy and democratic thought : Pennsylvania, 1776-1860 , 1948 .

[23]  T. Dworkin,et al.  Do Good and Get Rich: Financial Incentives for Whistleblowing and the False Claims Act , 1992 .

[24]  R. Tomasic,et al.  Taxation law compliance and the role of professional tax advisers* , 1991 .

[25]  Philippe C. Schmitter,et al.  Modes of Interest Intermediation and Models of Societal Change in Western Europe , 1977 .