Turning Waste into By-Product

This paper studies how a firm can create and capture value by converting a waste stream into a useful and saleable by-product (i.e., implementing by-product synergy (BPS)). We show that BPS creates an operational synergy between two products that are jointly produced. In essence, BPS is a process innovation that reduces the marginal cost of the original product and/or the by-product. The firm creates value through this process innovation and can capture this value by capturing newly created market opportunities, taking market share from competitors, or licensing the innovation to its competitors. We determine the optimal operating and licensing strategies for the firm and find market conditions under which the firm would benefit most from implementing BPS. We show that the optimal operating and licensing strategies are driven by the size of the cost reduction enabled by the BPS process innovation. We also show that leveraging the synergies between the original product and by-product can lead to counterintuitive profit-maximizing operating strategies such as increasing the amount of waste generated, and strategically increasing the quantity of original product above the business as usual production volume. We present a framework for assessing the environmental impact of BPS that incorporates the impact of the optimal operating and licensing strategies.

[1]  Ruud H. Teunter,et al.  Matching Demand and Supply to Maximize Profits from Remanufacturing , 2003, Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag..

[2]  Mark E. Ferguson,et al.  The Effect of Competition on Recovery Strategies , 2006 .

[3]  D. V. Beers,et al.  Industrial Symbiosis in the Australian Minerals Industry: The Cases of Kwinana and Gladstone , 2007 .

[4]  Neil Genzlinger A. and Q , 2006 .

[5]  Luk N. Van Wassenhove,et al.  Remanufacturing as a Marketing Strategy , 2008, Manag. Sci..

[6]  Qinghua Zhu,et al.  Industrial Symbiosis in China: A Case Study of the Guitang Group , 2007 .

[7]  Gabriel R. Bitran,et al.  Co-Production Processes with Random Yields in the Semiconductor Industry , 1994, Oper. Res..

[8]  V. Guide,et al.  Closed‐Loop Supply Chains: An Introduction to the Feature Issue (Part 1) , 2006 .

[9]  M. Chertow,et al.  Quantifying economic and environmental benefits of co-located firms. , 2005, Environmental science & technology.

[10]  Ming-Deh A. Huang,et al.  Proof of proposition 2 , 1992 .

[11]  X. Wang,et al.  Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model , 1998 .

[12]  Yimin Wang,et al.  Pricing and Operational Recourse in Coproduction Systems , 2008, Manag. Sci..

[13]  Markets Linked by Rising Marginal Costs: Implications for Multimarket Contact, Recoupment, and Retaliatory Entry , 2007 .

[14]  K. Palmer,et al.  Optimal policies for solid waste disposal Taxes, subsidies, and standards , 1997 .

[15]  Hing Kai Chan,et al.  Don't forget your supplier when remanufacturing , 2013, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[16]  L. Beril Toktay,et al.  Cost Allocation in Manufacturing–Remanufacturing Operations , 2011 .

[17]  Stefan Baumgärtner,et al.  Joint Production, Externalities, and the Regulation of Production Networks , 2000 .

[18]  H. Groenevelt,et al.  COMPETITION IN REMANUFACTURING , 2001 .

[19]  Marian Chertow,et al.  INDUSTRIAL SYMBIOSIS: Literature and Taxonomy , 2000 .

[20]  Margaret Walls,et al.  Can Downstream Waste Disposal Policies Encourage Upstream "Design for Environment"? , 2000 .

[21]  J. Ehrenfeld,et al.  Industrial Ecology in Practice: The Evolution of Interdependence at Kalundborg , 1997 .

[22]  Yehuda Bassok,et al.  Random Yield and Random Demand in a Production System with Downward Substitution , 1999, Oper. Res..

[23]  D. Fullerton,et al.  Policies for Green Design , 1996 .

[24]  Angappa Gunasekaran,et al.  Constructing sustainable supply chain under double environmental medium regulations , 2014 .

[25]  L. Beril Toktay,et al.  Market Segmentation and Product Technology Selection for Remanufacturable Products , 2005, Manag. Sci..

[26]  Jayashankar M. Swaminathan,et al.  Managing New and Remanufactured Products , 2006, Manag. Sci..

[27]  Erik Rolland,et al.  The design of reverse distribution networks: Models and solution procedures , 2003, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[28]  Ming-Deh A. Huang,et al.  Proof of proposition 1 , 1992 .

[29]  Mary Tripsas,et al.  Technology, Identity, and Inertia through the Lens of 'The Digital Photography Company' , 2008, Organ. Sci..

[30]  Gilvan C. Souza,et al.  Time Value of Commercial Product Returns , 2006, Manag. Sci..

[31]  Charles J. Corbett,et al.  Extending the Horizons: Environmental Excellence as Key to Improving Operations , 2006, Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag..

[32]  J. Geanakoplos,et al.  Multimarket Oligopoly: Strategic Substitutes and Complements , 1985, Journal of Political Economy.

[33]  Stefan Baumgärtner,et al.  The concept of joint production and ecological economics , 2001 .

[34]  Rachel Gordon,et al.  Cook Composites and Polymers Co. , 2009 .

[35]  M. Toffel The Growing Strategic Importance of End-of-Life Product Management , 2003, IEEE Engineering Management Review.

[36]  L. V. Wassenhove,et al.  Sustainable Operations Management , 2005 .

[37]  Luk N. Van Wassenhove,et al.  Closed - Loop Supply Chain Models with Product Remanufacturing , 2004, Manag. Sci..

[38]  Luk N. Van Wassenhove,et al.  Product Reuse Economics in Closed‐Loop Supply Chain Research , 2008 .

[39]  Erwin van der Laan,et al.  Quantitative models for reverse logistics: A review , 1997 .

[40]  Gabriel R. Bitran,et al.  Deterministic approximations to co-production problems with service constraints , 1992 .

[41]  Leonard M. Adleman,et al.  Proof of proposition 3 , 1992 .