Coordination of Decisions in a Spatial Model of Brownian Agents

Brownian agents denote a particular class of heterogeneous agents that combines features of reactive and reflexive agent concepts. As one major advance, the Brownian agent concept allows the derivation of macroscopic equations from the agent dynamics, which can be used to analyze and predict the behavior of the MAS. As an application of the concept, we discuss a binary choice problem where individual decisions are based on different local information generated by the agents. The spatial coordination of decisions in a multi-agent community is investigated both analytically and by means of stochastic computer simulations. We find that dependent on two essential parameters describing the local impact and the spatial dissemination of information either a definite stable minority/majority relation (single-attractor regime) or a broad range of possible values (multi-attractor regime) occurs. In the latter case, the outcome of the decision process becomes rather diverse and hard to predict, both with respect to the fraction of the majority and their spatial distribution. We also show that a more “efficient” information dissemination of a subpopulation provides a suitable way to stabilize their majority status and to reduce “diversity” and uncertainty in the decision process.

[1]  Alan Kirman,et al.  Economics with Heterogeneous Interacting Agents , 2001 .

[2]  Steven P. Schnaars Managing Imitation Strategies: How Later Entrants Seize Markets from Pioneers , 1994 .

[3]  F. Schweitzer,et al.  Modelling collective opinion formation by means of active Brownian particles , 1999, adap-org/9911005.

[4]  Andrzej Nowak,et al.  Social dilemmas exist in space , 1984 .

[5]  S. Galam Rational group decision making: A random field Ising model at T = 0 , 1997, cond-mat/9702163.

[6]  J. Hołyst,et al.  Phase transitions as a persistent feature of groups with leaders in models of opinion formation , 2000 .

[7]  Dirk Helbing,et al.  Simulating dynamical features of escape panic , 2000, Nature.

[8]  Frank Schweitzer,et al.  Self-Organization of Complex Structures: From Individual to Collective Dynamics - Some Introductory , 1997 .

[9]  Wulf Albers,et al.  Social dilemmas and cooperation , 1994 .

[10]  D. Lane,et al.  Decision Rules and Market Share: Aggregation in an Information Contagion Model , 1996 .

[11]  Dietrich Stauffer,et al.  Anual Reviews of Computational Physics VII , 1994 .

[12]  W. Arthur,et al.  The Economy as an Evolving Complex System II , 1988 .

[13]  T. Lux Herd Behaviour, Bubbles and Crashes , 1995 .

[14]  Heinz Mühlenbein,et al.  Coordination of Decisions in a Spatial Agent Model , 2001, ArXiv.

[15]  James H. Liu,et al.  Distance Matters: Physical Space and Social Impact , 1995 .

[16]  Nicolaas J. Vriend,et al.  Self-organization of markets: An example of a computational approach , 1995 .

[17]  B. Hillier,et al.  The Social Logic of Space , 1984 .

[18]  Alan Kirman,et al.  Ants, Rationality, and Recruitment , 1993 .

[19]  F. Schweitzer,et al.  SOCIAL IMPACT MODELS OF OPINION DYNAMICS , 2001 .

[20]  Frank Schweitzer,et al.  Modeling complexity in economic and social systems , 2002 .

[21]  B. Latané,et al.  From private attitude to public opinion: A dynamic theory of social impact. , 1990 .

[22]  T. Schelling Models of Segregation , 1969 .

[23]  G. A. Kohring,et al.  Ising Models of Social Impact: the Role of Cumulative Advantage , 1996 .

[24]  Wolfgang Weidlich,et al.  Physics and social science — The approach of synergetics , 1991 .

[25]  A. Banerjee,et al.  A Simple Model of Herd Behavior , 1992 .

[26]  F. Schweitzer Brownian Agents and Active Particles , 2003, Springer Series in Synergetics.

[27]  J. M. Sakoda The checkerboard model of social interaction , 1971 .

[28]  B. Latané,et al.  Statistical mechanics of social impact. , 1992, Physical review. A, Atomic, molecular, and optical physics.