The Evaluation of Cultural Heritage: Some Critical Issues

Decisions on preserving art objects and art institutions are continually taken by governments and public administrations. Preservation implies maintaining the stock and hindering its dilapidation and worsening. Keeping up the stock creates opportunity cost as the resources involved (labour and material inputs, and in the case of historic monuments especially the sites) could be used for alternative purposes. Current funds are needed to repair and safeguard the objects. In order to take these decisions rationally an evaluation of the value of the cultural heritage (compared with relevant alternatives) is required.

[1]  Iris Bohnet,et al.  Direct‐Democratic Rules: The Role of Discussion , 1994 .

[2]  C. D. Throsby,et al.  Measuring the demand for the arts as a public good: theory and empirical results. , 1983 .

[3]  Richard C. Bishop,et al.  Measuring Values of Extramarket Goods: Are Indirect Measures Biased? , 1979 .

[4]  Hartmut Kliemt,et al.  The veil of insignificance , 1986 .

[5]  Bruno S. Frey,et al.  Direct democracy: Politico-economic lessons from Swiss experience , 1994 .

[6]  Paul R. Portney,et al.  The Contingent Valuation Debate: Why Economists Should Care , 1994 .

[7]  J. Knetsch Assumptions, Behavioral Findings, and Policy Analysis , 1995 .

[8]  F. Martin Determining the size of museum subsidies , 1994 .

[9]  Berry Ives,et al.  Bidding games for valuation of aesthetic environmental improvements , 1974 .

[10]  A. Sen,et al.  Environmental Evaluation and Social Choice: Contingent Valuation and the Market Analogy , 1995 .

[11]  J. Knetsch The Endowment Effect and Evidence of Nonreversible Indifference Curves. , 1989 .

[12]  V. Smith,et al.  Congestion, quality deterioration, and optimal use: Wilderness recreation in the Spanish peaks primitive area , 1973 .

[13]  J. Knetsch Environmental Valuation: Some Problems of Wrong Questions and Misleading Answers1 , 1994, Environmental Values.

[14]  J. Knetsch,et al.  Consumer's Surplus Measures and the Evaluation of Resources , 1979 .

[15]  J. Hausman,et al.  Contingent Valuation: Is Some Number Better than No Number? , 1994 .

[16]  Maureen L. Cropper,et al.  The effect of information on health risk valuations , 1992 .

[17]  R. S. Rosomoff,et al.  The life you save may be your own. , 1996, The Clinical journal of pain.

[18]  D. Throsby The Production and Consumption of the Arts: A View of Cultural Economics , 1994 .

[19]  M. Cropper,et al.  Environmental Economics: A Survey , 1992 .

[20]  Bruce W. Marion,et al.  The Influence of Consumer Price Information on Retail Pricing and Consumer Behavior , 1980 .

[21]  Bruno S. Frey,et al.  Muses and Markets: Explorations in the Economics of the Arts , 1989 .

[22]  R. Thaler Toward a positive theory of consumer choice , 1980 .

[23]  Jack L. Knftsch ASYMMETRIC VALUATION OF GAINS AND LOSSES AND PREFERENCE ORDER ASSUMPTIONS , 1995 .

[24]  B. Frey,et al.  Should Social Scientists Care about Choice Anomalies? , 1989 .

[25]  J. Muellbauer,et al.  Economics and consumer behavior , 1980 .

[26]  W. Morrison,et al.  Subsidies for the performing arts: Evidence on voter preference , 1986 .

[27]  A. Sen,et al.  Isolation, Assurance and the Social Rate of Discount , 1967 .

[28]  Kevin J. Boyle,et al.  Measuring Natural Resource Damages with Contingent Valuation: Tests of Validity and Reliability , 1993 .

[29]  W. Michael Hanemann,et al.  Valuing the Environment through Contingent Valuation , 1994 .

[30]  Gebhard Kirchgässner,et al.  Low-cost decisions as a challenge to public choice , 1993 .